|
In this essay I attempt to describe 'money'
and 'value' in real terms and identify the most common fallacies one reads in
the common literature.
|
|
|
But before we dig in to the morass of
theories about money and about value, here is an interesting and relevant
digression. When one adds 2 to 2 one some times comes up with 5 or 6. In this
case we have an interesting book purchased to learn more about Mesopotamian
economic and political life. But we find it contains many valuable insights
into the study of economics - including of course money and ideas about value
just as relevant to today's actions by the Federal Reserve. This is The
Ancient Economy: Evidence and Models, edited by J. .G. Manning and Ian
Morris.
|
|
|
Despite 'money' and 'value' being critical
and fundamental concepts central to the entire economist profession for its
understanding of how a 'economy' actually functions, there is no consensus
among economists as to the meaning of either. The arguments flow back and
forth, as is so common in many similar discussions, the participants frequently
are simply 'talking' past or over each other. One fundamental cause of the
reasoning system some authors employ is that some are secular materialists who
even deny that any actors in economic affairs in the past could actually
believe in metaphysical concepts and hence base their actions on such beliefs.
And others do believe real actors did base their actions on metaphysical
beliefs but then dismiss those ideas as irrational. .
Here are several 'standard' discussions on money and economic thought. Others
are at the end of this essay. Note the fundamental basis of all these theories
about economic activities - they are theories. This is the 'deductive' method
coming from Plato as opposed to an evidence based 'inductive' method coming
from Aristotle. The most 'theoretical' of them are based on pure thinking by
individuals who claim to be utterly 'rational' in their own thought processes,
without reference to examination of the events recorded in human history. In
fact some economists go so far as to claim that historical 'facts' are not
'facts' and should be ignored. They presume, on their rational basis, a few
axioms and then work backwards from those to construct a 'must have been'
psudo-historical record. Others did attempt to base their 'reasoned' analysis
on some historical facts but lacked access to the actual historical record
which was not literally 'unearthed' until recently. Yet there followers -fans -
persist on the basis of these savants reputation to stick with the early ideas.
But the fundamental problem with relying on theorists espousing economic
theories is the same as relying on those promotiing political theories. When
theories are compared with actual events and results of their application in
practice (if that happens) is note the remarkable congruence of such theories
with the political policies they seek to legitimize. Thus, in the era of rulers
claiming 'the divine right of kings' there are theories supporting that. Slave
holding societies produce multiple theoretical claims to justify it.
Politicians who want to expand their government power favor economic theories
that justify that. Or putting it in reverse economists who seek advancement
from politicians wanting 'big' government will conceive theories that support
them.
Here are a few standard encyclopedia descriptions or definitions about money
and theories about economics. I will also include links to books and articles
about money.
|
|
|
History of Economic Thought
|
|
|
History of Money
|
|
|
Classical Economics
|
|
|
Austrian School Economics
|
|
|
Keynesian Economics
|
|
|
Keynesian vs. Austrian Economics
|
|
|
Credit Theory of Money
|
|
|
State Theory of Money
|
|
|
Quantity Theory of Money
|
|
|
"liquidity preference"
|
|
|
Money
|
|
|
Store of Value
|
|
|
Unit of Account
|
|
|
Medium of Exchange
|
|
|
Velocity of Money
|
|
|
Principles of Economics
|
|
|
History of Macroeconomic Thought
|
|
|
Debt Deflation
|
|
|
Modern Monetary Theory
|
|
|
Chartalism
|
|
|
|
|
|
As with money, there are various different
ideas expressed by theoriticians about 'value'. And some authors simply ignore
the subject.
In my view, 'Value' is a psychological phenomena. And 'money' is another
psychological concept that is created as a means for describing the relative
'value' of goods and services. "Money' in turn is depicted by notations in
written ledgers or by tokens created to represent it physically. But both
'value' and 'money' are essentially concepts - not myths, but ideas. And the
content of the concepts of 'value' and 'money' are closely related and
determined by the underlying belief in a purely materialist or in a
fundamentally metaphysical reality.
|
|
|
Economists define 'money' in terms of three
functions that they claim it serves.
One is as a 'measure of account', which means the 'value' of objects and labor
and other things can be entered as numerical representations in written
ledgers. Then they can be compared 'objectively'. But, of course, the actual
relationship between the number assigned to one thing and that of another is
subjective.
The second is as a 'medium of exchange', which means that tokens (coins, slips
of paper, tally sticks, or physical commodities like sea shells, (or now
digital entries on computers) can be exchanged between parties to represent the
'value' of the goods or services being exchanged. This method avoids the
so-called 'double problem' if people wishing to sell have to find an individual
wishing to buy that same thing and the reverse. Some theorists consider this
'money' to be a commodity subject to their laws relating to supply and demand
for commodities. While others believe that, whatever the physical medium is,
its attribute as 'money' is purely representational.
The third function is as a 'store of 'value', which means that the 'value'
represented by the tokens or by the numerical marks in the ledger will retain
this 'value' over time, so that it can be accepted equally for both sides of an
exchange and can be presumed to remain the same between the time it is
exchanged for goods and the time its holder will exchange it for other goods.
More about this function below. As I mentioned theorists who consider this as a
'function' of money don't all agree in what constitutes 'value'.
The historical record shows that at various times and in various places these
three functions were fulfilled by different representations. For instance,
ducks, sparrows and eagles are all 'birds' and in like manner the forms by
which 'money' performs each of those three functions need not be the same.
|
|
|
|
|
|
Human activity
Humans are the only species of life that innately attempts to justify its own
existence.
In fact, life itself, consists of repeated exchanges of goods and services.
Goods and services is a category that includes both material and non-material
items. Material are everything from ping pong balls to furniture and houses to
air craft carriers. Non-material items include power, loyalty, honor, glory,
friendship, prestige, love and many other similar concepts.
The fundamental and most important asset that each human possesses is time and
the second is knowledge. Time is unique in several ways.
First, it is the only asset that is obtained without exchange with another
asset, but it can be exchanged for any good or service.
Second, it depreciates almost immediately, in the course of a single day, but
is received, again, on the following day. Depreciation means a decline in the
relative value of an asset.
Third, it is the property of each individual. Once the asset of the time
provided by a single day is gone it cannot be retrieved, but another day is
given next. In order to make use of the time in a day the individual must
exchange it promptly for an asset (good or service) that will not depreciate so
quickly. In important cases that asset is knowledge. But all assets depreciate
over time unless they are actively enhanced by their owner. For instance, new
knowledge is described by George Gilder as 'surprise'. The value of knowledge
depreciates as it becomes known and used by more and more people. The creation
of knowledge is an intensive capital expense and knowledge is capital.
Individuals may choose to exchange their day of time for some form of personal
pleasure, such as watching a movie or playing frizbee. But at some point they
will need to exchange their day of time for essential assets of food, clothing
and shelter, provided by someone else. Typically, they can do this either by
performing a service directly in exchange for such goods or services, or they
can learn to produce assets of value to others that then can be exchanged.
|
|
|
'Value'
The common idea is that goods and services as mentioned above 'have' value.
This is a mistake. And so is the idea of 'intrinsic value'. There is no such
thing. 'Value' is a psychological phenomena. It is a measure of a relative
'desire' or 'want' or 'feeling for' one asset in comparison with all the other
potential goods or services that the individual has available for choice. It is
the increments on the scale of priorities - preferences. Individuals from
childhood want to have or do everything they can think of NOW. The process of
maturation includes learning that one cannot have or do everything one desires
and especially not NOW. The individual must select, choose, what to want or to
do most out of the total available items. In other words, establish priorities.
'Value' then is the relative place on the scale of priorities that the
individual establishes for each good or service or personal action at a given
time and location. The 'value' the individual assigns to any specific good or
service or action is relative because it will change with the individual's
circumstances as well as with the relative availability of these in comparison
with all others. So 'value' is not an attribute that can be fixed to - attached
to - any object or asset (material on non-material). A good or service does not
have value, yet it can be 'valuable' because it can be desirable.
An essential aspect of individual freedom is the ability to decide for oneself
the 'relative value' of each available good or service or action. Slavery
essentially is the condition in which one has nearly no ability to decide
'values' for himself. (See further.) But to live successfully in a society, one
must abide by the limitations and relative 'values' the society places on the
range of goods, services, and actions. The individual lives in a community of
other individuals who also have scales of priority in which they place the same
desired goods and services. In a democratic society the range remains quite
broad. The more dictatorial or absolutist the rule of the government the
smaller the range of available goods, services and actions allowed to the
individual. In fact the exercise of 'power' amounts to the ability to determine
which of these (if any) are available to each individual. The ruler's scale of
relative 'values' takes the place over that of the individuals.
The there are two scales of priorities. One is the relative 'values' assigned
to the use of individual's available time and the other is the relative
'values' of the individual goods, services and activities that may be selected.
Governments will seek to control both scales.
Following an initial comment by Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx and
many other economists found the source of 'value' in labor - that hours or days
of work have 'value' in themselves. Marx, then, claimed that, if the money
prices of the products produced by labor were greater than the money wage
received by the worker, there must be a 'surplus value' that was being
confiscated from the worker by the employer.
It seems to me they had the situation backwards. The 'value' of the goods or
services produced by in individual, be him laborer or anyone else, is not
determined by the laborer (producer) himself (herself) but by the counter
parties who will receive them. The laborer (producer), having exchanged his
labor time for something he created, exchanges his production with a counter
party who is reciprocating by exchanging his own production - in other words,
for other products so their relative 'value' is established by the usual
relationship of 'supply and demand'. It is established either in a relatively
'free' market society or by the government in an authoritarian society. In a
centrally controlled economy the exchange may be indirect, in that the
producers deposit their products in a government controlled warehouse and draw
consumption goods back out of the warehouses.
|
|
|
If 'value' was an intrinsic attribute
attached to any thing, there could be no auctions or even trade. Everyone would
have the same assessment of the 'value' of the assets and each would have a
fixed price, and that quantity of 'money' would also have the same 'value' to
each potential bidder. And no one would voluntarily trade away a more valuable
asset in exchange for a less valuable one.
Or consider a simple relationship between two individuals, Mr. A and Mr. B in
which Mr. A has product X and Mr. B has product Y. Can they trade? If Mr. X
considers the 'value' of product Y to be greater than product X - AND Mr. B
considers the value of product X to be greater than product Y, then they can
exchange - in each case the individual receives a new product of greater
'value', in his opinion, to himself than what he gave. But if the two products
each had 'intrinsic value'; that is, their 'values' were attributes attached to
each so that both parties assigned the 'values' of each product the same as did
the other party, then they would not trade.
|
|
|
As Ludwig von Mises shows in his essential
book, Human Action, individuals have but one integrated hierarchy of
desires and one scale of prioritizing. But in the late 19th century the
academic communities decided to divide the study of human action into three
separate categories - economic, social, and political. So, since then
professional economists have created this mythical 'economic man' who
prioritizes all his actions on the pursuit of economic goals by maximizing his
'utility factor'. The other two disciplines also tend to study a model of man
whose actions are dominated by social or political motives. But this can miss
consideration of the real human motives that can be seen when the individual
seeks, for instance, greater economic assets to use them as means to achieve
social or political ends; or any other means and ends relationship that
combines the individual's assessment of 'value' in all three respects.
|
|
|
Production and Consumption:
Everything that is created - produced - is created by individuals. Products
created include both the material assets and non-material assets as mentioned
above. Some products can be created quickly, while others require years to be
created.
Everything consumed is consumed by individuals. Products are consumed when they
reach their final 'owner' and are no longer exchanged. Some products are
consumed rapidly, while others may remain useful and continue to exist for
years.
Everyone is of necessity of life a consumer and consumption takes place
continually and immediately. In primitive societies - hunters and gatherers -
producers and consumers were identical - producers consumed what they produced
and consumers had produced what they consumed. This relationship changed with
the development of agriculture and the specialization of labor. But even
nomadic societies typically divided production of specific items between
individuals having the most skill in their production. Then 'distribution' was
needed to enable the more complex exchange process.
But only a relatively few individuals in modern society are producers. And
production is episodic and future oriented, sometimes requiring a year or more
between the beginning of a production process and its achievement. And the
creation of a single thing will likely require the efforts of many producers.
(Think agriculture or finding and building a mine.) So producers, being also
consumers, must consume previously created products during the delayed interval
before their production process achieves results. That means they must already
have sufficient products to exchange for those they are consuming, or be able
to obtain them on the basis of credit. (A model of economic activity that does
not include this relationship is faulty.) But once their production process (if
successful) is generating a profit - surplus - they can expand production on
the basis of 'retained earnings' - sometimes called 'cash flow'.
Therefore, our definition:
Consumers - everyone is a consumer
Producers, individuals who devote at least some of their time by exchanging
their time to creation of something new of value to others.
Non-productive consumers, individuals who do not produce anything (or very
little) of value to others. (Obvious nonproductive consumers are children and
those too old or sick to continue producing). But they can include others who
are favored by social norms or by coercion and violence. Among these are rulers
(government officials) and their associates (including voters).
Rana Foroohar coins a great concept of this in the title of her book Makers
and Takers. She has in mind as 'takers' individuals, other than children
and ill, who live off the production of others without contributing to
production.
Thus, I categorize societies in two ways. Producers versus non-producers; and
rulers versus ruled.
|
|
|
The relationship between production and
consumption:
Every individual must consume to survive, thus consumption must have at least a
minimal level. This must be achieved by at least a minimal level of production
- and access to produced products. So some individuals must be producers. In
primitive societies production was limited by physical capacities, whereas
today, unfortunately, low levels of consumption are limited mostly by limited
access to greater quantities of production. Production must be distributed from
its producers to the consumers. In small, primitive societies this was
accomplished by sharing according to social norms - not barter. As societies
became larger, more 'advanced' and with increasing specialization of labor they
became organized in hierarchal structures in which rulers took charge of
organizing distribution. This invariably favored themselves (including their
supporting cadres). (See for instance, Karl Wittfogel, Oriental
Despotism.
|
|
|
Saving:
Only producers can save anything. Savings are the 'retained earnings' kept (not
consumed or invested) by the producers. Consumers as defined above do not and
cannot 'save' anything. The common term, savings, that are somethings not
consumed by consumers are actually a part of real savings from producers or
'gifts' from government remaining to consumers from what has been transferred
to them (not produced by them). And the 'gifts' from government actually are
savings from something created by producers, or simply 'gifts' created by
government edict..
L. Randall Wray in his tendentious book, Modern Money Theory
repeatedly claims that the purpose of all production is to
acquire 'money'. That is an old concept. I disagree, for me the purpose of
production is to create 'value'. 'Money' is only one symbol of 'value', but not
all 'value' is symbolized in 'money'. The theoretical concept that focuses on
'money' derives from the modern materialist view of reality, which in turn
considers economic activity as a process for achieving ends, when actually it
is only a process of prioritizing and achieving means.
|
|
|
'Value' and 'money':
An individual 'hermit' can make his decisions on choices of goods. services and
actions he will retain, consume or seek to create on the basis of internal
thought without needing to consider the choices of anyone else. But people live
in a society in which, as noted above, their neighbors also are making
decisions about the same products and activities. They naturally develop and
agree upon an external (but relative and temporary) scale onto which everyone
will then be able to advertise his priorities to everyone else. As societies
create more formal organization they establish government. One role of
government, then, is to create a practical mechanism for educating everyone so
they understand the scale of 'values' and can use it. In a broadly democratic
society the government promotes the scale of 'values' continually recreated by
the people. The more authoritarian the government the more it will want to
interfere and establish a scale that promotes its one set of 'values' and keep
it constant.
The scale of 'values' is described then by an abstract concept we call 'money.
With such an abstract overall concept well understood, individuals are able to
compare and make known to each other their opinions about the relative 'value'
of any products or actions under consideration for exchange. They are able to
recognize the 'values' both they have themselves and those of their
counter-parties as described above, when considering an exchange. The abstract
concept 'money' is, in a market organized society, expressed in terms called
'prices'. But first the concept of 'money ' was represented by notations in
ledgers created and kept by officials of local governments (rulers). Later, it
was also depicted in some physical form that people could recognize and use.
Today, the abstract concept 'money' is also represented in abstract terms
signified by entry in digital data bases.
There are three main functions that societies have recognized that this concept
'money' may perform.
One is as a 'measure of account'. That was the first function of government.
That means an accounting or 'book keeping' process in which the assets and
liabilities of parties may be compared with each other in terms of some
unchanging standard. The flow of assets and liabilities of the member parties
may be netted against each other without any physical representation changing
hands. So-called Giro systems are of this form and so is the Yap Island giant
stone circle. The advantage of using this system is that it is safe and does
not involve carrying a physical representation around. But a disadvantage is
that it is created by a ruler and government, not the individual people.
A second function is as a 'means of exchange'. This means some physical item
such as a cacao bean, metal coin, beaver pelt, barrel of tobacco, piece of
printed paper, or other of established and known 'value' can be exchanged as an
intermediate token good between exchanges of the final goods or services. The
huge advantage of developing and using this method is that it greatly expands
the flexibility of individual exchanges in time and space and enables
individuals to express their own idea of relative values of the products
directly.
The third commonly considered function of 'money' is as a 'store of value'. In
my opinion this is limited in nature because 'value' cannot really be 'stored'.
In order for 'money' to be a 'store of value' its 'value' (expressed in
whatever token form it takes) must be guaranteed by some authority. Otherwise,
the 'value' of the 'money' will be subject to the same relativity as other
things or ideas including depreciation.
|
|
|
Credit and debt
|
|
|
|
|
|
"Velocity" of Money - This is the
link to my extended discussion of the concept of 'velocity' of money
|
|
|
Biographies or identifications of significant
economists or their theories or books
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Warren Mosler - Apparently obtained
sufficient wealth from the hedge fund he created to dabble in politics and
bulding expensive automobiles as well as learn about MMT from Wray and others.
He is prolific author claiming the value of MMT
|
|
|
George Fredrich Knapp - The author of
State Theory of Money and now the champion of the 'chartalist' theory of
money creation now advocated by the MMT theorists
|
|
|
Carl Menger - one of the 19th - early 20th
century founders of the "Austrian school' of economic theory
|
|
|
Michal Kalecki - Influencal Polish
theoritician in 1940's who formulated mathmatical equations and model
supporting state capitalism and origin of MMT -
Described by Antony Mueller
|
|
|
Alfred Mitchell-Innes -
|
|
|
Lawrence H. White - economics professor -
author of Clash of Economic Ideas
|
|
|
Bill Mitchell
|
|
|
Robert P. Murphy
|
|
|
Lord John Maynard Keynes - The most
influential economist of the 20th century and beyond. But strongly challenged
by others.
|
|
|
Liquidity Preference - Invented by Lord
Keynes as a theory to explain the origin of interest rates as the 'demad' for
money. It presumes money is an asset - a commodity - It is depicted in the
IS/LM model. But other economists believe that interest rates are a result of
the time preference for having anything NOW versus having it at some future
time. Interest is then demanded for abstaining from having it now in favor of
having it later.
|
|
|
Say's Law of Markets - developed by French
economist, J. B. Say around 1810. Asserts economic theory that supply will
always create demand. Disparanged and ignored by Keynesian economists
|
|
|
Murray Rothbard - self styled
anachro-capitalist - one of the leading economists following Ludwig von Mises -
libertarian - author of many books on economics, history and politics. strong
advocate of very small government or none at all.
|
|
|
Frederick Hayek - Student of Ludwig von Mises
-Nobel Prize winner - author of Road to Serfdom - leader in Austrian
School.
|
|
|
Ludwig von Mises - Austrian economist -
prolific author - Human Action -leader of the Austrian School of
economic theory
|
|
|
Methodenstreit - name coined for the
conflict in late19th century between Austrian School and German Historical
School advocates of different findamental bases for economic theory.
|
|
|
anarcho- Capitalism -Advocated by Murray
Rothbard - believes in almost no role for government in human affairs.
|
|
|
Catallactics - Advocated as method in theory
of economics by von Mises
|
|
|
praxeology - the 'science' of human behavior
advocated by von Mises as the basis for developing economic theory
|
|
|
Richards, Jay - Money, Greed and God
|
|
|
Cantillion, Richard - Wikipedia
|
|
|
Cantillion, Richard, Founder
|
|
|
Cantillion, Richard - An Essay on the Nature
of Trade in General
|
|
|
Cantillion, Richard - An Essay
|
|
|
Cantillion, Richard -
|
|
|
References: A list of some books and articles
devoted mostly or at least significantly on the subjects of money, credit,
debt, or investment
|
|
|
Mishkin, Frederic S. - The Economics of
Money, Banking & Financial Markets
|
|
|
Ingham, Geoffrey - The Nature of Money
|
|
|
Ingham, Geoffrey - Capitalism
|
|
|
Otteson, James-The Essential Adam Smith
|
|
|
Martin, Felix - Money - The Unauthorized
Biography
|
|
|
Kwarteng, Kwasi - War and Gold: A 500-year
history of Empires, Adventures, and Debt
|
|
|
Fischer, David Hackett - The Great Wave:
Price Revolutions and the Rhythm of History
|
|
|
Tamny, John - Who Needs the FED
|
|
|
Davies, Glyn - History of Money: From
Ancient Times to the Present Day
|
|
|
Dorn, James, A. ed. - Monetary
Alternatives: Rethinking Government Fiat Money
|
|
|
Kindleberger, Charles - Manias, Panics,
and Crashes
|
|
|
Graeber, David - Debt: The First 5,000
Years
|
|
|
Hudson, Michael - .... and forgive them
their debts
|
|
|
Selgin, George - The Myth of the Myth of
Barter
|
|
|
Selgin, George - Graeber, Once More
|
|
|
Weatherford, Jack - The History of
Money
|
|
|
Admati, Anat & Martin Hellwig - The
Bankers' New Clothes: What's Wrong with Banking and What to Do about It
|
|
|
Calomiris, Charles W. & Stephen H. Haber
-Fragile by Design: The Political Origins of Banking Crises & Scarce
Credit
|
|
|
Reinhart, Carmen M. & Kenneth S. Rogoff -
This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly
|
|
|
Conti-Brown, Peter - The Power and
Independence of the Federal Reserve
|
|
|
Foroohar, Rana - Makers and Takers: The
Rise of Finance and The Fall of American Business
|
|
|
King, Stephen D. - When the Money Runs
Out: The end of Western Affluence
|
|
|
Whalen, R. Christopher -
Inflated: How Money and Debt Built the American Dream
|
|
|
Forbes, Steve & Elizabeth Ames -
Money: How the Destruction of the Dollar Threatens the Global Economy - and
What We Can Do About It
|
|
|
Gordon, David - Review of Forbes book -
Money: How the Destruction of the Dollar Threatens the Global Economy
|
|
|
Gordon, David - Review of Israel Kirzner book
- collection on Ethics and the Legacy of Austrian Economics
|
|
|
Gilder, George -The Scandal of Money: Why
Wall Street Recovers but the Economy Never Does
|
|
|
Gilder, George Wealth and Poverty
|
|
|
Gilder, George Life after Google
|
|
|
Mehrling, Perry - The New Lombard
Street
|
|
|
Wray, L. Randall - A Chartalist Critique
of John Locke's Theory of Property, Accumulation, and Money
|
|
|
Wray, L. Randall -Modern Money Theory
|
|
|
Wray, L. Randall - Money: An Alternative
Story
|
|
|
Mitchell, Roger Malcolm - Monetarily
Soverign: The Key to Understanding Economics
|
|
|
Mitchell, Roger Malcolm - How You Can
Change the World with Just two Words
|
|
|
Mitchell, Roger Malcolm - How You Can
Prevent Recessions and Depressions
|
|
|
Mosler, Warren - Modern Monetary Theory
(MMT) in a Nutshell
|
|
|
Mosler, Warren - Seven Deadly Innocent
Frauds of Economic Policy
|
|
|
Edwards, Sebastian - Modern Monetary
Theory: Cautionary tales from Latin America
|
|
|
Daily KOS article. Mosler's "Seven
Deadly innocent Frauds"_ a review, sort of.
|
|
|
Caffentzis, C. George - Hume, Money, and
Civilization; or, Why Was Hume a Metalists?
|
|
|
|
|
|
Wright, Robert - MMT Is a Recipe for
Revolution
|
|
|
Frankel, S. Herbert - Two Philosophies of
Money: The Conflict of Trust and Authority
|
|
|
Katusa, Martin - The Colder War: How the
Global Energy trade Slipped from America's Grasp
|
|
|
Rickards, James - The Death of Money: The
Coming Collapse of the International Monetary System
|
|
|
Rickards, James - Currency Wars: The
Making of the Next Global Crisis
|
|
|
Rickards, James - The Road to Ruin
|
|
|
White, Lawrence H. - The Clash of Economic
Ideas
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. Economic Thought
Before Adam Smith- An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought
Vol 1
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. Classical Economics -
An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought Volume II
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. - What has Government
Done to our Money?
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. - The Mystery of
Banking
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. - A History of Money
and Banking in the United States
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. - The Anatomy of the
State
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. - Man, Economy, and
State + Power and Market
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. - The Essential von
Mises
|
|
|
Rothbard, Murray N. - Conceived in Liberty
A Libertarian perspective history of the American colonies up to 1984.
|
|
|
Ferguson, Niall - The Ascent of Money
|
|
|
Ferguson, Niall - The Great
Degeneration
|
|
|
Ferguson, Niall - The Square and the
Tower
|
|
|
Polleit, Thorsten - Central Banks are
Messing with Your Head
|
|
|
Niemietz, Kristian - Socialism: The Failed
Idea that Never Dies
|
|
|
Kaufman, Henry - Tectonic Shifts in
Financial Markets
|
|
|
Booth, Danielle Dimartino - FED UP
|
|
|
Mises, Ludwig von - The Theory of Money
and Credit
|
|
|
Mises, Ludwig von - Human Action
|
|
|
Mises, Ludwig von -Theory and History
|
|
|
Mises, Ludwig von -Socialism
|
|
|
Mises, Ludwig von - The Anti-Capitalist
Mentality
|
|
|
Mises, Ludwig von - Lord Keynes and Say's
Law
|
|
|
Wikipedia article - Say's Law
|
|
|
Horowiz, Steven - Understanding Say's
Lawsee above
|
|
|
Mises, Ludwig von - Bureaucracy
|
|
|
Mises, Ludwig von - Liberalism
|
|
|
Manish, G. P. A Brief Defense of Mises's
Conception of Time Preference and His Pure Time Preference Theory of
Interest
|
|
|
Kates, Stephen Why Your Grandfather's
Economics Was Better than Yours: On the Catastrophic Disappearance of Say's
Law
|
|
|
Coogan, Philip - Paper Promises; Debt,
Money and The new World Order
|
|
|
Manning J. G. and Jan Morris - The Ancient
Economy
|
|
|
Fox, Justin - The Myth of the Rational
Market
|
|
|
Conti-Brown, Peter - The Power and
Independence of the Federal Reserve
|
|
|
Selgin, George - The Theory of Free
Banking: Money Supply under Competitive Note Issue
|
|
|
Selgin, George - Fractional Reserve
Banking
|
|
|
Selgin, George - Money Free and Unfree
|
|
|
Selgin, George - MMT's Big Coin Gambit
|
|
|
Selgin, George - Floored
|
|
|
Selgin, George - The Modern New Deal
That's Too Good to Be True
|
|
|
Board of Governors - Federal Reserve -
Federal Reserve System
|
|
|
Tamny, John - Your Move, Gold Critics:
Please Explain What Money Is
|
|
|
Murphy, Robert- George Selgin
Misunderstands Rothbard's Position on Fractional Reserve Banking
|
|
|
Murphy, Robert - The Upside Down World of
MMT
|
|
|
Hudson, Michael - ...and forgive them
their debts
|
|
|
Hudson, Michael - Finance as Warfare
|
|
|
Hudson, Michael - A Travesty of Financial
History
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Shostak, Frank - The problem with Modern
Monetary Theory
|
|
|
Shostak, Frank - Why the Boom-Bust Cycle
Keeps Repeating
|
|
|
Shostak, Frank - Easy Money is Driving the
Boom-Bust Cycles
|
|
|
Shostak, Frank - Money Velocity and
Economic Growth
|
|
|
Salerno, Joseph - Fractional Reserves and
the Fed
|
|
& |
Salerno, Joseph - The Sociology of the
Development of Austrian Economics
|
|
|
Landes, David, Joel Mokyr & William
Baumol, eds. - The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient
Mesopotamia to Modern Times
|
|
|
Podany, Amanda- Brotherhood of Kings
|
|
|
Podany, Amanda - Mesopotamia
|
|
|
History of Mesopotamia
|
|
|
Third Dynasty of Ur
|
|
|
Ebla -Wealthy and powerful kingdom with
capital of same name in north-west modern Syria -
|
|
|
Uruk Period
|
|
|
History of Sumer
|
|
|
Reden, Sitta von - Money in Classical
Antiquity
|
|
|
Facts and Details - Mesopotamian Economics
and Money
|
|
|
Melloan, George- Great Money Binge:
Spending our Way to Socialism
|
|
|
Lewis, Hunter- Where Keynes went Wrong
|
|
|
Salsman, Richard - Gold and Liberty
|
|
|
Johnston, Michael - Going for Gold
|
|
|
Lewis, Nathan K. - Gold the Final
Standard
|
|
|
Romer, Paul - The Trouble with
Macroeconomics
|
|
|
Morgan, Theodore - Introduction to
Economics
|
|
|
Magness, Philip W. - Postmodern Monetary
Theory
|
|
|
Bernholz, Peter - Monetary Regimes and
Inflation
|
|
|
Newman, Patrick - Book Review of
Bernholz'sMonetary Regimes and Inflation
|
|
|
Wiggin, Addison - The Demise of the
Dollar
|
|
|
Kay, John - Other People's Money
|
|
|
Gilder, George - The Scandal of Money
|
|
|
Mansharamani,- Vikram - Boombustology:
Spotting Financial Bubbles before they burst
|
|
|
Pollett, Thorsten - Central Banks Are
Propping Up Stock Prices
|
|
|
Pollett, Thorsten - The Fed Has No Choice
But to Return to Ultra-Low Interest Rates
|
|
|
Mueller, Antony - Where Does the Idea That
Deficits don't Matter Come From"
|
|
|
Mueller, Antony - The Neo-Marxist Rots of
Modern Monetary Theory
|
|
|
Kaketcki, Michal - economic equations
|
|
|
Hoppe, Hans-Hermann Banking, Nation
States, and International Politics: A Socological Reconstruction of the Present
Economic order
|
|
|
Klein, Matthew C. Debating Modern Monetary
Theory
|
|
|
Klein, Matthew C. The Fed's Shrinkage
Problem
|
|
|
Murray, Justin - Billioaires Aren't Quite
As Rich as We Think They Are
|
|
|
Kelton, Stephanie & Randall Wray -
Answers from the MMTers
|
|
|
Muir, Kevin - The Macro Tourist
-Practitioner's Guide to MMT: Part I
|
|
|
Muir, Kevin - The Macro Tourist -
Practitioner's Guide to MMT: Part 2
|
|
|
Muray, Justin - How Central Bank Interest
-Rate - Policy is Destabilizing Banks
|
|
|
Hunt, Lacy - Hoisington - Quarterly Review
and Outlook
|
|
|
Hay, David - Bubble 3.0: The Intersection
of Bubble and Bubble
|
|
|
Hay, David - Bubble 3.0: A Blast From a
Bubble Past
|
|
|
Hay, David - Bubble 3.0: Can an Acronym
Save the World? (Part I)
|
|
|
Hay, David - Bubble 3.0: Can an Acronym
Save the World? (Part II)
|
|
|
Hay, David - Bubble 3.0: Chapter 10: No
Way Out
|
|
|
Weiss, Kai - Central Banks Contribute to
Inequality
|
|
|
Dwyer, Gerald P. - Quantitative Easing: A
model for Financing Government Spending?
|
|
|
Salter, Alexander W. - Interest Rates,
Funny Money, and Economic Malaise
|
|
|
|
|