{short description of image}  
 

MONETARY REGIMES AND INFLATION

Peter Bernholz

Subtitle: History, Economic and Political Relationships, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham U.K., 2003, 210 pgs., index. sources, tables, paperback

 
 

Reviewer Comment -
The author does not include enough attention to ancient and medieval economic history. And in the chapter in which he does mention some aspects of ancient history he included mistakes. He does discuss paper money and its impact on inflation in relation to currency, but does not consider credit. He appears to consider as 'money' only currency. And he continues the typical myth about barter . His study of modern monetary inflations is detailed and excellent. But he cites Gresham's Law a dozen times when discussing currency debasement. It appears to be his 'all purpose' cause. The 'law' states that 'bad' money will drive 'good' money out of circulation. He uses this idea repeatedly, but then he also writes of situation for 'reference' GL - namely that 'good' money drove 'bad' money out of circulation. Does he also believe there are cases of 'reverse gravity'? And is it that 'bad money drives 'good money' out of circulation or that 'good money' is exported as the necessary exchange for imports leaving only the 'mad money' to circulate.

The specific cases do have historical records. The idea is that when a sovereign 'debases' that is mints a new coin with less silver and more other metal but establishes its official 'value' at the same level, the public will use the debased currency and horde the old, but where does the old go and why. But we know that some of the specific cases were that the original 'good' silver coins were already going out of country to pay for imports - from Rome to China or from Europe to China - and it was the resulting shortage of coins for daily use that required the sovereign to re-mint and increase the quantity of coins. In other cases, it was the sovereign who called in the 'good' coins and reminted them debased as 'bad' coins. So of course the 'good' coins disappeared - right into the mint. The book is an econometrics product, full of math and tables and models.

Since this is the 2003 edition of the book the author could not include anything about the monetary regime in the 2008 financial crisis. He has published a new edition in 2015. I do not have this as yet. But Patrick Newman wrote a review in the Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol 19 #2, summer 2016. Newman writes that the only significant changes are in Chapter 2 and Chapter 9. In Chapter 2 Bernholz attempts to answer the question - why a very large increase in its portfolio, which constitutes MO did not create an equivalent increase in M2? This may be responsible for the lack of inflation expected from this increase in the money supply. And Newman notes that Bernholz did not mention the shift in Fed payments to banks for placing excessive reserves with the Fed. This is the central thesis of Seglin's book, Floored!
I have more discussion of this in separate reviews of those two references.

 
 

Chapter 1 Introduction:
The author writes that inflation 'presupposes the existence of money' ... so 'It follows that inflation cannot be older than money'. But these ideas rest on an assumption that 'value' is measured in relative terms - the relationship between the 'value' ascribed to a unit of 'money' and the 'value'ascribed to particular goods and services being considered. This concept is 'monetarist' theory. Please read Fischer's study of the history of waves of price increases and decreases in Europe since the 12th century The Great Waves. Along with much data and extensive discussion, Fischer describes the severan very different 'schools of historians' in terms of their understanding of the causes of price increases (inflation) of which the monetarist is but one.
Bernholz does provide a clear definition for what he means as 'inflation'. "We will use the term 'inflation' only for an increase of the price level extending over a longer period, usually several years, as measured by one or several prices indices.' He states the book will describe historical facts concerning inflations and on that basis explain political and economic causes of inflation and then develop a macroeconomic model of these relationships. Finlly he will discuss how inflations can be ended. But Fischer's historical descriptions indicate the reality is much more complex than this. For one thing, Fischer's descriptions based on longer historical eras indicate that waves of extended prices (and declines) of goods and services over Europe as a whole had noting to do with 'monetary regimes' or with the individual rulers and their governments.

Basically the problem is that all assessments of 'value' are relative in which the 'value' of anything is some ratio to the value of everything else on interest to individuals and society. A standard measure of 'value' is a ratio between a good or service and a measure called 'money'. But both are constantly changing. Moreover, when the 'money' used in daily exchange is constituted in some 'precious' metal the 'value' of the weight of the actual metal is also changing with respect to the government standard 'value' it assigns to the coin made of a weight of that metal.
In summary, I don't believe in the 'monetarist' theory of value..

 
 

Chapter 2 - Inflation and monetary regimes:
In this chapter Bernholz begins:

2.1 Inflation: long-term historical evidence
"We turn first to the long-term development of inflation since about 1800 in several countries belonging for decades to the most highly developed economies of the world. (his graph includes Great Britain, France, Swizerland and the United States) The graph shows a fluctuating flat line from 1790 to about 1910, and then a rapidly accelerating rise to 1998 in which France rose by far the most.
This corresponds to Fischer's (and standard historical assessments) that the 19th century was one of the three eras in Western Europe of deflation and to Fischer's identification of the20th century as one of the periodic greatest increasing waves of price increase. His second graph depicts cost of living increasing in several countries between 1950 and 2000 with all the increase occuring after 1970-75.
He then infers the following conclusions
1.'an inflationary development can be oberved for the whole period': NO, it cannot, the wave of increase only occured after 1910. The 19th century experienced one of the best eras of price stability and even deline due to the massive rapid increase in productivity and great reducion in the cost of transportation and communications.
2. 'inflation has accelerated since about 1970': Yes, and the likely reasons are clear.
3. 'after 1970 two groups of counries show different inflaionary developments' His answer comes in section 2.3

2-2 description of different monetary regime:He defines a 'monetary regime' as 'the set of rules governing the institutions and organizations which finally determine the amount of money supplied"
(Note here that according to this definition there were no 'monetary regimes' during much of European history as there was no organization determining the amount of money during lengthy periods and multiple independent organizations each attempting to create money during other eras. Yet there were clearly observable recuring waves of price increase and decline.)
But Bernholz defines the regimes thusly:
1 "Metallic stndards like gold and silver, or copper, in which coins circulate, whose nominal face value corresponds to the value of the metal contained in the coin." (Really? Seems to me that mints produced coins whose official value was greater than the market value of the metal itself - called signorage). He mentions this as a posibiliy. His further description is confusing.

2."In history several weakened metallic standards have existed". By this he means conditions in which exchange of gold or silver with bank notes was restricted.
3."A third monetary system is given by the discretionary paper money standard" By this he means that the monetary authorities can increase or decrease the quantity of paper money in circulation. His description of the details of this system is lengthy.

2-3 Monetary regimes and inflation Bernhholz's commentary in this section is, based on a monetarist conception, and lengthy and convoluted. But his conclusions follow:
1. "Metallic standards like the gold or silver standard show no or , as we will see in the next chapter, a much smaller inflationary tendency than discretionary paper money standards" This may be so, but it does not consider the other factors during the 19th century

2 "Paper money standards with central banks independent of political authorities are less inflation-biased than those with dependent central banks". This also may be true. But the U.S. did not have a central bank from 1837 to 1913, yet the period was one of stable prices and even deflation.

3. "Currencies based on discretionary paper standard and bound by a regime of a fixed exchange rate to currencies....." a very lengthy description follows. Again, likely true but the author's history does not prove it becaue he ignores many factors besides gold and silver coin.
Bernholz now returns to elaborate on section 2.1 and graphs 1 and 2.

2-4 The inflationary bias of political systems:
In this section Bernholz addresses the question remaining from the previous section. - "why different monetary regimes show such remarkable differences in their inflation performances, the hypothesisis advanced that governments have an inherent bias towrds inflation."
Wow, we don't need elaborate economic theories to answer this. All history shows that rulers (and everyone else) always have unlimited desires for more. They simply confiscate production when they are able including by tribute or by asserting that they own the production of the goods and services. Or they exchange 'money' that they create and then take it back by taxes.But Bernholz devotes 3 pages to explain this. But there have been periods throughout history when prices of goods and services rose in great waves due to the simple laws of supply and demand, when demand greatly exceeded supply. And these had nothing to do with either governments or monetary systems.

2-5 The influence of monetary regimes:
In this short section Bernholz notes the obvious. The demands by rulers for more money even if it involves depreciating the exchange value of the measure of value and inflation can only be prevented if, as he writes, 'the hnds of the rulers are bound by an adequate monetary regime or constitution'. No doubt so far this has not happened and it is a reason the sovereigh considers the control of money his monopoly. But Bernholz describes the 19th century 'stability' purely in monetary terms and claims that the gold standard prevented governments (England) from expanding the real supply of money. Read Lombard Street to refute this.
2-6 Some other characteristics of monetary constitutions:
He continues by asking, "under which conditions is it probable or feasible that stable monetary regimes emerge.?" But he defers the discussion to a later chapter.

2-7 Conclusions:
In this section Bernholz asserts seven conclustions.
1. Political systems tend to favor inflationary bias for currencies. Lets amend that to conclude that such is not limited to currencies but even more to credit instruments.

2. "All hyperinflations in history have occured during the 20th century." We do not have sufficent historical data for prior centuries and regions to prove that correct or not.

3. "Monetary regimes binding the hands of rulers, politicians and governments are necessary conditions for keeping inflation at bay." Again, Fischer snows in his 'The Great Wave' that increases in prices have existed in major waves having nothing to do with rulers or governments.

4. "Metalic monetary regimes, especially the gold and silver standards, have shown the largest resistance to inflation, followed by independent central banks in such discretionary paper money regimes." What about exchecker tally sustems? What about the millenia before central banks existed?

5. "Compared to a regime based on a gold standard, a discretionary monetary regime with an independent central bank seems to show a smaller varance of variables like the growth rate of GDP, unemployment and real intrest rates." Considering the relaltive times in history when monetary regimes were based on a gold standard and when central banks existed I doubt if there is enough evidence to base this assertion.

6. "With flexible exchange rates there exist, however,a much greater variance and mid-term swings of exchange rates arond purchasing power parities...." No comment

7. "Given flexible exchange rates exist, .... " No comment

 
 

Chapter 3 - Inflation under metallic monetary regimes
Clearly, Bernholz is limiting his research here to societies that based their medium of exchange on currency - coins. That leaves out a huge part of history. And it rather predisposes the outcome. For instance, what about waves of price increases in societies that did not rely on metalic coins or in societies that did but experienced deflation.

3.1 Inflation caused by an additional supply of the monetary metal

The author writes: "Inflation has probably been a charactrtistc of himan history since money has been used as a means of payment." Lets make an exception for the extended eras of deflation and price stability in Western Europe and ignore unknowns such as Asia. Bernholz describes several well known events that have mixed assessments by historians. One is the wave of price increases in Europe in the 16th century. This has been attributed to the incease of silver and gold that was brought from the new Spanish colonies in America. But some historians cite the timing of this and report that the price rise began prior to the arrival of silver and gold, as Bernholz, himself, honestly notes. According to Adam Smith, what eventually happened is that the price of silver declined so much that people were eager to get ride of it and the cost of production in European silver mines versus price of silver forced local mines to close. He mentions the famous incident in which Alexander The Great looted the vast Persion treasure and put it into circulation to pay troops. (No one thinks to ask why the King of Kings did not need to use that gold himself.) Alexcander's use to pay troops is an example of what some historians believe is the main origin of coinagte - the intriduction of mercentary soldiers in Greek and Near Eastern warfare required a mobile and universally acceptable system of payment.

3.2 The debasement of metal standards by rulers.
Indeed, rulers seem to have a predelicting to'debase' their coinage, by one way or another.

3-3 Reasons for the introduction and maintenance of stable metallic monetary regimes.

3-4 Price and exchange controls.

3-5 Consequences of inflation for the real economy.

3.6 Conclusion

 
 

Chapter 4 - Moderate paper money inflations

4.1 The introduction of paper money

4.2 Paper money inflation in Sweden during the 18th century

4.3 Paper money inflation in Massachusetts, 1703 - 1749

4.4 Inflation during the American War of Independence

4.5 Paper money inflation during the American Civil War

4.6 Chinese paper money inflation under the Ming regime

4.7 Conclusion

 
 

Chapter 5 - Characteristics of hyperinflations

5.1 Some characteristics of the French hyperinflation

5.2 Hyperinflations are caused by government budget deficits

5.3 Real Stock of money and currency substitution

5.4 Under valuation and currency substitution

5.5 *Other characteristics of hyperinflation

5.6.1 Consequences of high inflation for capital markets

5.6.2 The development of prices

5.7 Economic activity and unemployment

5.8 The political economy of high inflation

5.9 Social and political consequences of hyperinflation

5.10 Conclusion

 
 

Chapter 6 - Currency competitions, inflation. Gresham's Law and exchange rate

6.1 Introduction
In this chapter Bernholz creates a mathmatical 'model' by which he wants to describe how an episode of inflation passes through 4 states of a 'cycle'. He writes: "The four periods contain characteristics corresponding to stylised facts which have been observed in many hisorical cases of inflation, and most of which have been described above."
He describes the four phases. Then he writes, "In setting up the model it will be assumed, as already mentioned, that domestic agents hold both a a stable and an inflating kind of money and that only the former is a also demanded in the rest of the world." Page by page he adds more and more letters that are symbols of various constants or variables. And he repeatedly resurts to 'assumptions'.
I have a gradate degree in engineering and science and am well used to mathmatics in hard sciences. But, frankly, I can not fathom these 'equations' and math tranformations to undestand if they actually mean anything. So lets skip the rest of the chapter. He does throw in Gresham's Law here and elseware, but it has several applications in different circumstances. His example here and 'model' and that it applies to domestic inflation but somehow in the context of international trade.

6.2 Empirical evidence for periods one to three

6.3 *The model

6.4 *First period: introduction of paper money

6.5 *Second period: fixed exchange rate and loss of official reserves

6.6 *Third period: Gresham's Law at work

6.7 *Fourth Period: The return of good money

6.8 Conclusion

 
 

Chapter 7 - Ending mild or moderate inflation

7.1 Conditions favoring the stabilization of moderate inflation

7.2 Restoration of stable monetary constitutions after wars at the old parity

7.3 Preconditions for returning to a stable monetary regime at a new parity

7.4 Further discussion of historical examples

7.5 More recent historical examples

7.6 Conclusion

 
 

Chapter 8 - Currency reforms ending hyperinflations

8.1 Introduction

8.2 Political-economic preconditions for initiating successful reforms

8.3 Sufficient economic and institutional conditions for successful currency reforms

8.4 Characteristics of most successful currency reform: Empirical evidence

8.5 Less and least successful reforms

8.6 The influence of wrong evaluations of reform packages by the public

8.7 Conclusions

 
 

Appendix:
Sources for historical data not identified in the text and literature relating to different causes of hyperinflation

 
 

Review:
-Dr. Bernholz has published a second edition of this important book in 2015, in which he left the original chapters alone and added two new chapters. This edition was reviewed by Patrick Newman in the Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol., 19, No2, pgs.`87-191, Summer, 2016. The reviewer then focused his comments on these two chapters. He begins by discussing the financial crisis of 2007-8 and the reactions to it by academic economists. One issue was the huge monetary expansion the major central banks created and their increase in the reserves of the major member banks. The purpose was to provide liquidity and stimulate economic activity. The expectation was fear that this would generate also massive inflation (in accordance with standard economic theory) - and debase (depreciate) national currencies. .

 
 

New Chapter 2
In this the author asks - where is all the inflation that was predicted? He contrasts the significant increase in bank reserves with the very moderate increase in consumer prices. He suggests seeveral reasons including that banks did not expand loaning, the money was spent on items not included in the CPI, the increase in M0 was not passed on to an increase in M2, and 'velocity' of money declined. Newman notes that Bernholz could have provided more specific statistics to strengthen his assessment.

 
 

New Chapter 9
In this chapter Bernholz attempts to answer two questions - Why did stable monetary systems occur prior to an inflation? And, what caused stable monetary systems to be abolished.

 
 

References

 
{short description of image}

George Selgin - Floored! A very different explaination for the period after the financial crisis of 2008

 
{short description of image}

Patrick Newman - Review of this book in which Newman notes a shortcoming in Bernholz's analysis

 
{short description of image}

David Hackett Fischer -The Great Wave A much deeper and more historically based study of waves of price increase and decrease in European history.

 
{short description of image}

Sitta von Reden -[ Money in Classical Aniquity She provides much more detailed information and resulting analysis of price changes

 
{short description of image}

Felix Martin - Money: The Unauthorized Biography A much more detailed history of 'money' not limited to coinage.

 
{short description of image}

George Selgin - Money Free and Unfree

 
{short description of image}

Amanda Podany -Mesopotamia She includes much more information on the components of 'money' and monetary standards in ancient Mesopotamia

 
{short description of image}

Frederic Mishkin - The Economnics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets Fifth Edition

 
{short description of image}

Frederic Mishkin - The Economnics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets Ninth Edition

 
{short description of image}

Geoffrey Ingham - The Nature of Money

 
{short description of image}

Ludwig von Mises - The Theory of Money and Credit

 
{short description of image}

Glyn Davies - History of Money from ancient times to the present day

 
{short description of image}

Lawrence White - The Clash of Economic Ideas

 
{short description of image}

Lawrence White - The Theory of Monetary Institutions

 
{short description of image}

David Graeber - Debt: The First 5.000 Years

 
{short description of image}

Michael Hudson - .... and forgive them their debts

 
{short description of image}

David S. Landes - The Invention of Enterprise

 
{short description of image}

James Dorn, ed. - Monetary Alternatives

 
{short description of image}

Nathan K. Lewis - Gold, the Final Standard

 

Return to Xenophon.