{short description of image}  
 

NORMATIVE ECONOMICS

WIKIPEDIA ENTRY

{short description of image}

This is an exract from the Wikipedia entry

 
 

Reviewer comment:
A brief description of the development of a theoritical basis for linking economic action and a theory that justifies it to 'fairness' as a political goal. As the entry notes -it is about 'what OUGHT to be in the mind of the theoritician. Below the Wikipedia entry we have an even more explicit article about 'normative economics' and it is interesting in that the author includes Adam Smith as a major theoritician.

 

 

Normative economics (as opposed to positive economics) is a part of economics whose objective is fairness or what the outcome of the economy or goals of public policy ought to be.[1] Economists commonly prefer to distinguish normative economics ("what ought to be" in economic matters) from positive economics ("what is"). Many normative (value) judgments, however, are held conditionally, to be given up if facts or knowledge of facts changes, so that a change of values may be purely scientific.[2] On the other hand, welfare economist Amartya Sen distinguishes basic (normative) judgements, which do not depend on such knowledge, from nonbasic judgments, which do. He finds it interesting to note that "no judgments are demonstrably basic" while some value judgments may be shown to be nonbasic. This leaves open the possibility of fruitful scientific discussion of value judgments.[3] Positive and normative economics are often synthesized in the style of practical idealism. In this discipline, sometimes called the "art of economics," positive economics is utilized as a practical tool for achieving normative objectives. An example of a normative economic statement is as follows: The price of milk should be $6 a gallon to give dairy farmers a higher living standard and to save the family farm. This is a normative statement, because it reflects value judgments. This specific statement makes the judgment that farmers deserve a higher living standard and that family farms ought to be saved.[1]

Subfields of normative economics include social choice theory, cooperative game theory, and mechanism design. Over time, divergence in normative economics has given rise to various economic schools of thought as various intellectuals and economists have debated over the effectiveness and morality of various economic systems. In the modern era, these have been broadly classified into "left" and "right" leaning patterns. Simply put, left-leaning economic thought tends to advocate for government intervention in the economy; on the other hand, right-leaning economic thought tends to advocate for minimal government intervention in the economy.
Capitalism, largely developed by the Dutch and British, is a right-leaning economic ideology that calls for market factors to determine production and consumption. Capitalist normative economic philosophy is attributed to Adam Smith. Communism, which has spread to many corners of the globe, advocates for state-controlled determination of production and consumption. Communist theory is widely attributed to Karl Marx and Freidrich Engels. Much of modern politics revolves around the normative economic debate over state involvement in the economy and various other normative economic theories exist. Some earlier technical problems posed in welfare economics and the theory of justice have been sufficiently addressed as to leave room for consideration of proposals in applied fields such as resource allocation, public policy, social indicators, and inequality and poverty measurement.[4]


See also :
Distribution (economics) Economic ideology Is-ought problem Justice (economics) Normative science Positive economics Social welfare function Social choice theory Welfare economics Economic progressivism

 
 

This another description of What is Normative Economics?{short description of image}

Normative economics is a school of thought which believes that economics as a subject should pass value statements, judgments, and opinions on economic policies, statements, and projects. It evaluates situations and outcomes of economic behavior as morally good or bad. Normative economics, as opposed to positive economics, tells us whether certain aspects of the economy are helpful or harmful. These evaluations are subject to the opinions of the people making the statements and are often without any basis or facts.

Examples of Normative Economics:
The regulation of oil prices by the government helps to keep inflation in check.
The independence of the central bank from the government should be curtailed.
The development of Special Economic Zones is not working out.
Progressive taxation is better than regressive taxation.
Companies should be made to pay for the pollution they cause.

All of the above statements are subjective. They represent nothing more than an individual’s opinion on an economic situation or policy. Economists are often guided by their personal value systems while making such statements.
Welfare economist and Nobel laureate Amartya Sen distinguishes normative statements into two parts. According to him, basic statements do not depend on any knowledge of facts or theories, whereas non-basic statements depend on the facts or knowledge of facts.

Origin of Normative Economics:
Normative economics first originated from “old-style welfare economics,” which is a simplified version of Pigou’s Economics of Welfare. “New welfare economics” came as the second form of normative economics in the 1930s. It used the Pareto Principle and the Compensation Principle to make normative statements about policies and state whether they were improving welfare or not. The latest forms of normative economics are social choice theory and public economics. Public economics studies the effects of the public sector on society and the economy as a whole. The social choice theory uses the method of voting to aggregate individual choices to indicate social preferences.

Prominent Normative Economists:
1. Adam Smith Adam Smith was a Scottish economist, philosopher, and author in the 18th century. He is well known for two of his publications – “The Theory of Moral Sentiments” and “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.” In “The Theory of Moral Sentiments”, Smith states sympathy as the initiation of action in society. His arguments about moral sentiments and sympathy as the foundation of rules and justice paved the way for modern normative economics.

2. Amartya Sen Amartya Sen is a 20th-century Indian economist and a Nobel laureate. Sen tried to discuss the distinction between positive and normative economics in his book “Economic Behavior and Moral Sentiments.” He emphasizes the fact that since welfare economics have a significant impact on actual behavior, ethical considerations should have a greater role in welfare economics, which, according to him, have been largely ignored. Normative Economics vs. Positive Economics Positive economics, on the other hand, concerns itself with only stating facts and figures. It does not pass any judgment on any economic policy or economic behavior. The major difference between positive economics and normative economics is that the statements made by positive economics can be tested for their validity. They may either be true or false, but can always be tested. Conversely, judgments passed by normative statements cannot be tested for their validity because of their subjectivity. For example, let us consider a positive statement, “The unemployment rate prevailing in the economy currently is 8%.” We know that there are measures to test whether this statement is true or not. Together with positive statements, normative statements help policymakers and leaders to reach opinion-based solutions to prevailing economic issues. Hence, both positive and normative economics play a vital role in the functioning of an economy.

 

Return to Xenophon.