|
If the supply of caviar were as plentiful as the supply of potatoes,
the price of caviarthat is, the exchange ratio between caviar and money
or caviar and other commoditieswould change considerably. In that case,
one could obtain caviar at a much smaller sacrifice than is required today.
Likewise, if the quantity of money is increased, the purchasing power of the
monetary unit decreases, and the quantity of goods that can be obtained for one
unit of this money decreases also.
When, in the sixteenth century, American resources of gold and silver were
discovered and exploited, enormous quantities of the precious metals were
transported to Europe. The result of this increase in the quantity of money was
a general tendency toward an upward movement of prices in Europe.
(Actually it was the increase in the quantity of silver which was the every day
currency The value of silver fall so far that European silver mines went out of
business. But most graphical representations show, for instance the quantity of
grain versus an oz of silver, which indicates this increase in 'value' of a
quantity of grain versus the 'value' of an oz of silver not that it is a
decrease of the 'value' of silver versus grain. JS)
In the same way, today, when a government increases the quantity of paper
money, the result is that the purchasing power of the monetary unit begins to
drop, and so prices rise. This is called inflation. Unfortunately, in the
United States, as well as in other countries, some people prefer to attribute
the cause of inflation not to an increase in the quantity of money but, rather,
to the rise in prices.
(Exactly, because people are shown the relationship, as I note, that makes it
appear that it is the price of a good that is increasing rather than the price
of money that is decreasing. And people are taught to think of a price of goods
in terms of money rather than the price of money in terms of goods. JS)
However, there has never been any serious argument against the economic
interpretation of the relationship between prices and the quantity of money, or
the exchange ratio between money and other goods, commodities, and services.
Under present day technological conditions there is nothing easier than to
manufacture pieces of paper upon which certain monetary amounts are printed. In
the United States, where all the notes are of the same size, it does not cost
the government more to print a bill of a thousand dollars than it does to print
a bill of one dollar. It is purely a printing procedure that requires the same
quantity of paper and ink.
I. In the eighteenth century, when the first attempts were made to issue bank
notes and to give these bank notes the quality of legal tenderthat is,
the right to be honored in exchange transactions in the same way that gold and
silver pieces were honoredthe governments and nations believed that
bankers had some secret knowledge enabling them to produce wealth out of
nothing. When the governments of the eighteenth century were in financial
difficulties, they thought all they needed was a clever banker at the head of
their financial management in order to get rid of all their difficulties.
Some years before the French Revolution, when the royalty of France was in
financial trouble, the king of France sought out such a clever banker, and
appointed him to a high position. This man was, in every regard, the opposite
of the people who, up to that time, had ruled France. First of all he was not a
Frenchman, he was a foreignera Swiss from Geneva, Jacques Necker.
Secondly, he was not a member of the aristocracy, he was a simple commoner. And
what counted even more in eighteenth century France, he was not a Catholic, but
a Protestant. And so Monsieur Necker, the father of the famous Madame de
Staël, became the minister of finance, and everyone expected him to solve
the financial problems of France. But in spite of the high degree of confidence
Monsieur Necker enjoyed, the royal cashbox remained emptyNeckers
greatest mistake having been his attempt to finance aid to the American
colonists in their war of independence against England without raising taxes.
That was certainly the wrong way to go about solving Frances financial
troubles. There can be no secret way to the solution of the financial problems
of a government; if it needs money, it has to obtain the money by taxing its
citizens (or, under special conditions, by borrowing it from people who have
the money).
But many governments, we can even say most governments, think there is another
method for getting the needed money; simply to print it.
(Actually the government instead of exchanging its currency for goods or
services to pay, it issues credit and the banking system pays by passing that
credit to the public via additions to their bank ballances or creates 'money'
in the form of bank notes. American paper money are bank notes issued by the
Federal Reserve, not from the Treasry. JS)
If the government wants to do something beneficialif, for example, it
wants to build a hospitalthe way to find the needed money for this
project is to tax the citizens and build the hospital out of tax revenues. Then
no special price revolution will occur, because when the government
collects money for the construction of the hospital, the citizenshaving
paid the taxesare forced to reduce their spending. The individual
taxpayer is forced to restrict either his consumption, his investments or his
savings. The government, appearing on the market as a buyer, replaces the
individual citizen: the citizen buys less, but the government buys more. The
government, of course, does not always buy the same goods which the citizens
would have bought; but on the average there occurs no rise in prices due to the
governments construction of a hospital. I choose this example of a
hospital precisely because people sometimes say: It makes a difference
whether the government uses its money for good or for bad purposes. I
want to assume that the government always uses the money which it has printed
for the best possible purposespurposes with which we all agree. For it is
not the way in which the money is spent, it is the way in which the government
obtains this money that brings about those consequences we call inflation and
which most people in the world today do not consider as beneficial. For
example, without inflating, the government could use the tax-collected money
for hiring new employees or for raising the salaries of those who are already
in government service.
Then these people, whose salaries have been increased, are in a position to buy
more. When the government taxes the citizens and uses this money to increase
the salaries of government employees, the taxpayers have less to spend, but the
government employees have more. Prices in general will not increase. But if the
government does not use tax money for this purpose, if it uses freshly printed
money instead, it means that there will be people who now have more money while
all other people still have as much as they had before. So those who received
the newly-printed money will be competing with those people who were buyers
before. And since there are no more commodities than there were previously, but
there is more money on the marketand since there are now people who can
buy more today than they could have bought yesterdaythere will be an
additional demand for that same quantity of goods. Therefore prices will tend
to go up. This cannot be avoided, no matter what the use of this newly-issued
money will be.
(This is true and von Mises makes it clear that the tax actually is a term for
'tribute' the (ruler) government issues the same 'money' that it takes back
from the public - meaning that the ruler as confiscated a portion of private
production for its own use. Prices don't go up but the people loose part of the
product of their production. Wealth has been confiscted and redistributed. JS)
II. And more importantly, this tendency for prices to go up will develop step
by step; it is not a general upward movement of what has been called the
price level. The metaphorical expression price level
must never be used. When people talk of a price level, they have in
mind the image of a level of a liquid which goes up or down according to the
increase or decrease in its quantity, but which, like a liquid in a tank,
always rises evenly. But with prices, there is no such thing as a
level. Prices do not change to the same extent at the same time.
There are always prices that are changing more rapidly, rising or falling more
rapidly than other prices. There is a reason for this. Consider the case of the
government employee who received the new money added to the money supply.
People do not buy today precisely the same commodities and in the same
quantities as they did yesterday. The additional money which the government has
printed and introduced into the market is not used for the purchase of all
commodities and services. It is used for the purchase of certain commodities,
the prices of which will rise, while other commodities will still remain at the
prices that prevailed before the new money was put on the market.
Therefore, when inflation starts, different groups within the population are
affected by this inflation in different ways. Those groups who get the new
money first gain a temporary benefit. When the government inflates in order to
wage a war, it has to buy munitions, and the first to get the additional money
are the munitions industries and the workers within these industries. These
groups are now in a very favorable position. They have higher profits and
higher wages; their business is moving. Why? Because they were the first to
receive the additional money. And having now more money at their disposal, they
are buying. And they are buying from other people who are manufacturing and
selling the commodities that these munitions makers want. These other people
form a second group. And this second group considers inflation to be very good
for business. Why not? Isnt it wonderful to sell more? For example, the
owner of a restaurant in the neighborhood of a munitions factory says: It
is really marvelous! The munitions workers have more money; there are many more
of them now than before; they are all patronizing my restaurant; I am very
happy about it. He does not see any reason to feel otherwise.
The situation is this: those people to whom the money comes first now have a
higher income, and they can still buy many commodities and services at prices
which correspond to the previous state of the market, to the condition that
existed on the eve of inflation. Therefore, they are in a very favorable
position. And thus inflation continues step by step, from one group of the
population to another. And all those to whom the additional money comes at the
early state of inflation are benefited because they are buying some things at
prices still corresponding to the previous stage of the exchange ratio between
money and commodities.
(Yes, again, and in today's economy the new money goes first to the insiders in
the financial industry and they take a cut out of the new money and exchange it
for other assets. Check the Forbes annual list of most wealthy Americans, the
top members show their fortunes were made in 'finance'. JS)
But there are other groups in the population to whom this additional money
comes much, much later. These people are in an unfavorable position. Before the
additional money comes to them they are forced to pay higher prices than they
paid before for someor for practically allof the commodities they
wanted to purchase, while their income has remained the same, or has not
increased proportionately with prices. Consider for instance a country like the
United States during the Second World War; on the one hand, inflation at that
time favored the munitions workers, the munitions industries, the manufacturers
of guns, while on the other hand it worked against other groups of the
population. And the ones who suffered the greatest disadvantages from inflation
were the teachers and the ministers. As you know, a minister is a very modest
person who serves God and must not talk too much about money. Teachers,
likewise, are dedicated persons who are supposed to think more about educating
the young than about their salaries. Consequently, the teachers and ministers
were among those who were most penalized by inflation, for the various schools
and churches were the last to realize that they must raise salaries. When the
church elders and the school corporations finally discovered that, after all,
one should also raise the salaries of those dedicated people, the earlier
losses they had suffered still remained. For a long time, they had to buy less
than they did before, to cut down their consumption of better and more
expensive foods, and to restrict their purchase of clothingbecause prices
had already adjusted upward, while their incomes, their salaries, had not yet
been raised. (This situation has changed considerably today, at least for
teachers.) There are therefore always different groups in the population being
affected differently by inflation. For some of them, inflation is not so bad;
they even ask for a continuation of it, because they are the first to profit
from it.
We will see, in the next lecture, how this unevenness in the consequences of
inflation vitally affects the politics that lead toward inflation. Under these
changes brought about by inflation, we have groups who are favored and groups
who are directly profiteering. I do not use the term profiteering
as a reproach to these people, for if there is someone to blame, it is the
government that established the inflation. And there are always people who
favor inflation, because they realize what is going on sooner than other people
do. Their special profits are due to the fact that there will necessarily be
unevenness in the process of inflation.
III. The government may think that inflationas a method of raising
fundsis better than taxation, which is always unpopular and difficult. In
many rich and great nations, legislators have often discussed, for months and
months, the various forms of new taxes that were necessary because the
parliament had decided to increase expenditures. Having discussed various
methods of getting the money by taxation, they finally decided that perhaps it
was better to do it by inflation. But of course, the word inflation
was not used. The politician in power who proceeds toward inflation does not
announce: I am proceeding toward inflation. The technical methods
employed to achieve the inflation are so complicated that the average citizen
does not realize inflation has begun.
One of the biggest inflations in history was in the German Reich after the
First World War. The inflation was not so momentous during the war; it was the
inflation after the war that brought about the catastrophe. The government did
not say: We are proceeding toward inflation. The government simply
borrowed money very indirectly from the central bank. The government did not
have to ask how the central bank would find and deliver the money. The central
bank simply printed it. Today the techniques for inflation are complicated by
the fact that there is checkbook money. It involves another technique, but the
result is the same. With the stroke of a pen, the government creates fiat
money, thus increasing the quantity of money and credit. The government simply
issues the order, and the fiat money is there.
IV. The government does not care, at first, that some people will be losers, it
does not care that prices will go up. The legislators say: This is a
wonderful system! But this wonderful system has one fundamental weakness:
it cannot last. If inflation could go on forever, there would be no point in
telling governments they should not inflate. But the certain fact about
inflation is that, sooner or later, it must come to an end. It is a policy that
cannot last. In the long run, inflation comes to an end with the breakdown of
the currency; it comes to a catastrophe, to a situation like the one in Germany
in 1923. On August 1, 1914, the value of the dollar was four marks and twenty
pfennigs. Nine years and three months later, in November 1923, the dollar was
pegged at 4.2 trillion marks. In other words, the mark was worth nothing. It no
longer had any value.
Some years ago, a famous author, John Maynard Keynes, wrote: In the long
run we are all dead. This is certainly true, I am sorry to say. But the
question is, how short or long will the short run be? In the eighteenth century
there was a famous lady, Madame de Pompadour, who is credited with the dictum:
Après nous le déluge (After us will come the
flood). Madame de Pompadour was happy enough to die in the short run. But
her successor in office, Madame du Barry, outlived the short run and was
beheaded in the long run. For many people the long run quickly
becomes the short runand the longer inflation goes on the
sooner the short run. How long can the short run last? How long can
a central bank continue an inflation? Probably as long as people are convinced
that the government, sooner or later, but certainly not too late, will stop
printing money and thereby stop decreasing the value of each unit of money.
When people no longer believe this, when they realize that the government will
go on and on without any intention of stopping, then they begin to understand
that prices tomorrow will be higher than they are today. Then they begin buying
at any price, causing prices to go up to such heights that the monetary system
breaks down.
I refer to the case of Germany, which the whole world was watching. Many books
have described the events of that time. (Although I am not a German, but an
Austrian, I saw everything from the inside: in Austria, conditions were not
very different from those in Germany; nor were they much different in many
other European countries.) For several years, the German people believed that
their inflation was just a temporary affair, that it would soon come to an end.
They believed it for almost nine years, until the summer of 1923. Then,
finally, they began to doubt. As the inflation continued, people thought it
wiser to buy anything available, instead of keeping money in their pockets.
Furthermore, they reasoned that one should not give loans of money, but on the
contrary, that it was a very good idea to be a debtor. Thus inflation continued
feeding on itself. And it went on in Germany until exactly November 20, 1923.
The masses had believed inflation money to be real money, but then they found
out that conditions had changed. At the end of the German inflation, in the
fall of 1923, the German factories paid their workers every morning in advance
for the day. And the workingman who came to the factory with his wife, handed
his wagesall the millions he gotover to her immediately. And the
lady immediately went to a shop to buy something, no matter what. She realized
what most people knew at that timethat overnight, from one day to
another, the mark lost 50% of its purchasing power. Money, like chocolate in a
hot oven, was melting in the pockets of the people. This last phase of German
inflation did not last long; after a few days, the whole nightmare was over:
the mark was valueless and a new currency had to be established.
V. Lord Keynes, the same man who said that in the long run we are all dead, was
one of a long line of inflationist authors of the twentieth century. They all
wrote against the gold standard. When Keynes attacked the gold standard, he
called it a barbarous relic. And most people today consider it
ridiculous to speak of a return to the gold standard. In the United States, for
instance, you are considered to be more or less a dreamer if you say:
Sooner or later, the United States will have to return to the gold
standard. Yet the gold standard has one tremendous virtue: the quantity
of money under the gold standard is independent of the policies of governments
and political parties. This is its advantage. It is a form of protection
against spendthrift governments. If, under the gold standard, a government is
asked to spend money for something new, the minister of finance can say:
And where do I get the money? Tell me, first, how I will find the money
for this additional expenditure. Under an inflationary system, nothing is
simpler for the politicians to do than to order the government printing office
to provide as much money as they need for their projects. Under a gold
standard, sound government has a much better chance; its leaders can say to the
people and to the politicians: We cant do it unless we increase
taxes. But under inflationary conditions, people acquire the habit of
looking upon the government as an institution with limitless means at its
disposal: the state, the government, can do anything.
If, for instance, the nation wants a new highway system, the government is
expected to build it. But where will the government get the money? One could
say that in the United States todayand even in the past, under
McKinleythe Republican party was more or less in favor of sound money and
of the gold standard, and the Democratic party was in favor of inflation, of
course not a paper inflation, but a silver inflation. It was, however, a
Democratic president of the United States, President Cleveland, who at the end
of the 1880s vetoed a decision of Congress, to give a small sumabout
$10,000to help a community that had suffered some disaster. And President
Cleveland justified his veto by writing: While it is the duty of the
citizens to support the government, it is not the duty of the government to
support the citizens. This is something which every statesman should
write on the wall of his office to show to people who come asking for money. I
am rather embarrassed by the necessity to simplify these problems. There are so
many complex problems in the monetary system, and I would not have written
volumes about them if they were as simple as I am describing them here. But the
fundamentals are precisely these: if you increase the quantity of money, you
bring about the lowering of the purchasing power of the monetary unit. This is
what people whose private affairs are unfavorably affected do not like. People
who do not benefit from inflation are the ones who complain. If inflation is
bad and if people realize it, why has it become almost a way of life in all
countries? Even some of the richest countries suffer from this disease. The
United States today is certainly the richest country in the world, with the
highest standard of living. But when you travel in the United States, you will
discover that there is constant talk about inflation and about the necessity to
stop it. But they only talk; they do not act.
VI. To give you some facts: after the First World War, Great Britain returned
to the prewar gold parity of the pound. That is, it revalued the pound upward.
This increased the purchasing power of every workers wages. In an
unhampered market the nominal money wage would have fallen to compensate for
this and the workers real wage would not have suffered. We do not have
time here to discuss the reasons for this. But the unions in Great Britain were
unwilling to accept an adjustment of money wage rates downward as the
purchasing power of the monetary unit rose. Therefore real wages were raised
considerably by this monetary measure. This was a serious catastrophe for
England, because Great Britain is a predominantly industrial country that has
to import its raw materials, half-finished goods, and food stuffs in order to
live, and has to export manufactured goods to pay for these imports. With the
rise in the international value of the pound, the price of British goods rose
on foreign markets and sales and exports declined.
Great Britain had, in effect, priced itself out of the world market. The unions
could not be defeated. You know the power of a union today. It has the right,
practically the privilege, to resort to violence. And a union order is,
therefore, let us say, not less important than a government decree. The
government decree is an order for the enforcement of which the enforcement
apparatus of the governmentthe policeis ready. You must obey the
government decree, otherwise you will have difficulties with the police.
Unfortunately, we have now, in almost all countries all over the world, a
second power that is in a position to exercise force: the labor unions. The
labor unions determine wages and then strike to enforce them in the same way in
which the government might decree a minimum wage rate. I will not discuss the
union question now; I shall deal with it later. I only want to establish that
it is the union policy to raise wage rates above the level they would have on
an unhampered market. As a result, a considerable part of the potential labor
force can be employed only by people or industries that are prepared to suffer
losses. And, since businesses are not able to keep on suffering losses, they
close their doors and people become unemployed.
(Actually it was Winston Churchill who insisted on resetting the pound-gold
ratio to its preWWI war level on the grounds of not upholding its value through
out the 'sterling' (Empire) countries. .JS)
The setting of wage rates above the level they would have on the unhampered
market always results in the unemployment of a considerable part of the
potential labor force. In Great Britain, the result of high wage rates enforced
by the labor unions was lasting unemployment, prolonged year after year.
Millions of workers were unemployed, production figures dropped. Even experts
were perplexed. In this situation the British government made a move which it
considered an indispensable, emergency measure: it devalued its currency. The
result was that the purchasing power of the money wages, upon which the unions
had insisted, was no longer the same. The real wages, the commodity wages, were
reduced. Now the worker could not buy as much as he had been able to buy
before, even though the nominal wage rates remained the same. In this way, it
was thought, real wage rates would return to free market levels and
unemployment would disappear.
(John Wood describes this event well in his book - Monetary Policy in
Democracies - as one of his examples of 'resumption' a policy of a
government to return to a gold standard after a period of inflationary 'paper
money". The legal ability of the private person to exchange the paper
'money' he holds for gold results in a rush to do just that. Lord Keynes
ascribed the phenomal to 'sticky wage rates' and people don't understand that
falling wages in an era of falling prices leaves them same. They don't
understand the difference between reducing wages along with prices and reducing
the real 'value' of the wages they receive. JS.)
This measuredevaluationwas adopted by various other countries, by
France, the Netherlands, and Belgium. One country even resorted twice to this
measure within a period of one year and a half. That country was
Czechoslovakia. It was a surreptitious method, let us say, to thwart the power
of the unions. You could not call it a real success, however. After a few
years, the people, the workers, even the unions, began to understand what was
going on. They came to realize that currency devaluation had reduced their real
wages. The unions had the power to oppose this. In many countries they inserted
a clause into wage contracts providing that money wages must go up
automatically with an increase in prices. This is called indexing. The unions
became index conscious. So, this method of reducing unemployment that the
government of Great Britain started in 1931which was later adopted by
almost all important governmentsthis method of solving
unemployment no longer works today.
In 1936, in his General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, Lord
Keynes unfortunately elevated this methodthe emergency measures of the
period between 1929 and 1933to a principle, to a fundamental system of
policy. And he justified it by saying, in effect: Unemployment is bad. If
you want unemployment to disappear you must inflate the currency. He
realized very well that wage rates can be too high for the market, that is, too
high to make it profitable for an employer to increase his work force, thus too
high from the point of view of the total working population, for with wage
rates imposed by unions above the market only a part of those anxious to earn
wages can obtain jobs. And Keynes said, in effect: Certainly mass
unemployment, prolonged year after year, is a very unsatisfactory
condition. But instead of suggesting that wage rates could and should be
adjusted to market conditions, he said, in effect: If one devalues the
currency and the workers are not clever enough to realize it, they will not
offer resistance against a drop in real wage rates, as long as nominal wage
rates remain the same.
In other words, Lord Keynes was saying that if a man gets the same amount of
sterling today as he got before the currency was devalued, he will not realize
that he is, in fact, now getting less. In old fashioned language, Keynes
proposed cheating the workers. Instead of declaring openly that wage rates must
be adjusted to the conditions of the marketbecause, if they are not, a
part of the labor force will inevitably remain unemployedhe said, in
effect: Full employment can be reached only if you have inflation. Cheat
the workers. The most interesting fact, however, is that when his General
Theory was published, it was no longer possible to cheat, because people had
already become index conscious. But the goal of full employment remained.
VII. What does full employment mean? It has to do with the
unhampered labor market, which is not manipulated by the unions or by the
government. On this market, wage rates for every type of labor tend to reach a
point at which everybody who wants a job can get one and every employer can
hire as many workers as he needs. If there is an increase in the demand for
labor, the wage rate will tend to be greater, and if fewer workers are needed,
the wage rate will tend to fall. The only method by which a full
employment situation can be brought about is by the maintenance of an
unhampered labor market. This is valid for every kind of labor and for every
kind of commodity. What does a businessman do who wants to sell a commodity for
five dollars a unit? When he cannot sell it at that price, the technical
business expression in the United States is, the inventory does not
move. But it must move. He cannot retain things because he must buy
something new; fashions are changing. So he sells at a lower price. If he
cannot sell the merchandise at five dollars, he must sell it at four. If he
cannot sell it at four, he must sell it at three. There is no other choice as
long as he stays in business. He may suffer losses, but these losses are due to
the fact that his anticipation of the market for his product was wrong. It is
the same with the thousands and thousands of young people who come every day
from the agricultural districts into the city trying to earn money.
It happens so in every industrial nation. In the United States they come to
town with the idea that they should get, say, a hundred dollars a week. This
may be impossible. So if a man cannot get a job for a hundred dollars a week,
he must try to get a job for ninety or eighty dollars, and perhaps even less.
But if he were to sayas the unions doone hundred dollars a
week or nothing, then he might have to remain unemployed. (Many do not
mind being unemployed, because the government pays unemployment
benefitsout of special taxes levied on the employerswhich are
sometimes nearly as high as the wages the man would receive if he were
employed.) Because a certain group of people believes that full employment can
be attained only by inflation, inflation is accepted in the United States. But
people are discussing the question: Should we have a sound currency with
unemployment, or inflation with full employment? This is in fact a very vicious
analysis. To deal with this problem we must raise the question: How can one
improve the condition of the workers and of all other groups of the population?
The answer is: by maintaining an unhampered labor market and thus achieving
full employment. Our dilemma is, shall the market determine wage rates or shall
they be determined by union pressure and compulsion? The dilemma is not
shall we have inflation or unemployment?
This mistaken analysis of the problem is argued in England, in European
industrial countries and even in the United States. And some people say:
Now look, even the United States is inflating. Why should we not do it
also. To these people one should answer first of all: One of the
privileges of a rich man is that he can afford to be foolish much longer than a
poor man. And this is the situation of the United States. The financial
policy of the United States is very bad and is getting worse. Perhaps the
United States can afford to be foolish a bit longer than some other countries.
The most important thing to remember is that inflation is not an act of God;
inflation is not a catastrophe of the elements or a disease that comes like the
plague.
Inflation is a policya deliberate policy of people who resort to
inflation because they consider it to be a lesser evil than unemployment. But
the fact is that, in the not very long run, inflation does not cure
unemployment. Inflation is a policy. And a policy can be changed. Therefore,
there is no reason to give in to inflation. If one regards inflation as an
evil, then one has to stop inflating. One has to balance the budget of the
government. Of course, public opinion must support this; the intellectuals must
help the people to understand. Given the support of public opinion, it is
certainly possible for the peoples elected representatives to abandon the
policy of inflation. We must remember that, in the long run, we may all be dead
and certainly will be dead. But we should arrange our earthly affairs, for the
short run in which we have to live, in the best possible way. And one of the
measures necessary for this purpose is to abandon inflationary policies.
(I disagree with the cause for government, and much of the public, to want
inflation. Inflation favors the debtor because his debt can be paid in less
'valuable' money and the creditor is hurt. The opposite results for creditors
and debtors follow from deflation. Since government are by far the largest
debtors and many of their voters are also debtors governments favor inflation.
JS)
|
|