{short description of image}  
 

THE NEW LOMBARD STREET

Perry Mehrling

 

Subtitle: How the Fed Became the Dealer of Last Resort, Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton, 2011, 174 pgs., index, references, notes

 
 

Reviewer comment:
Note the subtitle: "dealer of Last Resort". The author plays off of Bagehot's idea that the Bank of England became the 'lender of last resort' with the implicit mission to rescue banks in difficulty by lending them funds temporarily, backed by good collateral, and at significant interest rates. He shows that in the financial crisis of 2008 the Federal Reserve, and then other foreign banks bought up securities including mortgage paper from the commercial markets, to protect the investors in commercial paper such as money market funds, in effect becoming a financial dealer as well as a bank. His principle focus is on the 2007-8 crisis, but he provides a look back into several centuries of history to show how the situation of finance is different today. He relates this to Lombard Street in London, the historical center of international finance there. And the term 'Lombard' comes from it being a locus of the Italian (Lombard) bankers and their factors in late middle ages.
(Today's market economy is now termed 'financial capitalism')
The book is written in 'bank speak' for professional members of the financial industry including not only bank officials but also government financial ministry officials and regulators. It is about what they DO and also about their theories about what they are DOING or should be DOING and why. His focus is on 'credit' the central financial instrument that funds economic activity. But he equates 'credit' with 'money'. There is a difference between 'credit' BEING 'money' and credit being valued (measured) in terms of 'money'. He also uses the term 'cash' when he does not mean currency. The book was published in 2011 in time for a discussion of the origin, action and immediate results of the 2008 financial crisis. Throughout the book he contrasts the changing development of academic financial theories, naming some of the more famous creators, with the reality of financial actions in the material world credit markets. And he focuses on the differences and links between the financial market and the capital market..
In his conclusion chapter he accepts this new role of the FED as 'dealer of Last Resort' as a given condition and recommends that academic economic theory needs to 'fix the ideas' about what this means and how it should function. The reader here could skip the other chapters and read the conclusions.

But huge changes have taken place since then in fiscal and monetary actions that have created the massive 'debt' on the balance sheet of the FED. He want's FED intervention and 'management', but that has already shown its results in the 10 years subsequent to this book. So this is a history. It should be studied along with Chambers, Cooper, Reinhart/Rogoff, Prins, DiMartino Booth, and Fox, plus many more, including the host of authors writing about MMT.

 
 

 

 
 

Introduction:
The author wrote this book to answer the need to provide a financial history that can explain the crisis of 2007-8. He states: that "we need a historical perspective in order to understand our current predicament and to see beyond it to a possible future." "The intellectual challenge of producing such an account is large, given the scope of the crisis that is transforming not only banking and financial institutions and markets but also the regulatory and supervisory apparatus within which those institutions operate, including most dramatically the role of the Federal Reserve". He cites Walter Bagehot's "magisterial Lombard Street; A description of the Money market (1873)". But, he points out, the FED then did much more, which he terms "dealer of last resort". What the FED did and continues to do is "something completely new". He also includes Hyman Minsky and other academic financial theoreticians to discuss their theories about credit in the 'modern' that is current economy.
"A Money View Perspective"
"The fundamental purpose of this book is that a 'monetary view' provides the intellectual lens necessary to see clearly the central features of this multidimensional crisis. The reason is simple. It is in the daily operation of the money market that the coherence of the credit system, that vast web of promises to pay, is tested and resolved as cash flows meet cash commitments.
(He considers credit as cash because it is transferable and acts like physical coinage did in past times, we purchase things; that is, engage in an exchange of assets by using credit as the asset on one side of the exchange while the other side is a material asset, But in contrast to exchanging currency that credit creates a debt, a promise to create a material asset to complete the exchange.) And when an exchange is credit for credit more debt is created. In the era prior to 'financial capitalism' it was expected that the exchange would be completed by material assets, thus the credit/debt would be extinguished.

"The web of interlocking debt commitments, each one a more or less rash promise about an uncertain future, is like a bridge that we collectively spin out into the unknown future toward shores not yet visible." He describes two different points of view about the market - an economics view and a financial view. These are very different in their focus on past versus future and present. He believes the 'present is the natural sphere of the money view.' But both the economics and financial based viewers ignore the 'money view'. "As a consequence of this long domination of economics and then finance views, modern policymakers have lost sight of the Fed's historical mission to manage the balance between discipline and elasticity in the interbank payments system." "The rate of interest should reflect the price of time, not the price of liquidity."

" Lessons from the Crisis"
He writes that "Our thinking about money has mistaken the properties of models that formalize the economics and finance views for properties of the real world." This "has fueled the asset price bubble that created the conditions for the current crisis, and that bias will fuel the next bubble as well unless we learn the lesson that the current crisis has to teach."

And we have not learned. Moreover, we don't understand the real nature of a role of 'money'. And Dr. Mehrling uses the term 'money' when he means credit. Money actually is a metric, created to quantify 'value' of assets, goods and services, intellectual property, debt, credit, transgressions; everything. Since 'value' is a human concept the 'value' of anything and everything changes - it is relational- determined by time, scarcity, alternatives, - supply and demand for the asset being valued. So credit, which he correctly sees as the asset that performs the functions that popular nomenclature calls 'money' itself can and does change in value during its exchange and retention over time. He repeatedly states that 'credit is changing in value' at various times. Of course it does. This means that 'credit' has changed in the metric by which it is valued - that is money.
The basic problem in economic theory is that while the metric in which value of all assets is measured - that is 'money', at the same time the value of 'money' itself is changing. Consider an example from a different concept - length: it is measured in inches or meters or other materials. But when the length of something changes (expands or contracts) the size of the metric does NOT change. Simply, money is to value as the meter is to length.

Dr. Mehrling finds the origin of the financial problem in the concept developed by Harold Moulon in 1918, when the FED was first in action. He points to: "According to Moulton, American banks had improved on outdated British practice by relying of the 'shiftability' (or salability) of long -term security holdings to meet current cash needs, rather than on the 'self-liquidating' character of short-term commercial loans."

What this economic jargon means is this. Credit creates debt. Debt is a promise to PRODUCE something of value to complete an exchange transaction. One party exchanges some EXISTING asset for the promise that the other party will reciprocate in the future by providing some asset in return. In general, an asset he does not have at the moment. In British and general bank and market practice it was presumed that the debt would be canceled (and credit would disappear) within a short time. It was not presumed that the credit-debt instrument (paper) would be 'shifted' (meaning transferred) from its original owner as one side of another asset exchange in exchange for a current reciprocator to use a credit in another exchange, creating a long -term expansion of credit-debt in the total financial market. Credits are considered assets and debts are accounted for a liabilities. Thus, now the bank system has created a web in which the credit assets of parties are the liabilities of other parties and the reverse.

But Dr. Mehrling forgets that this kind of system, although not as wide spread, did exist in 16th-17th-18th century European markets and did enable financial crises when one bank or major merchant company did default of its debt liabilities triggering a wider financial 'bursting bubble' as debts lost by one party (its assets) then were lost causing debt defaults throughout the market system. His focus is on the "present system' which means the creation of the US Federal Reserve in 1913. He begins with a short discussion of the previous US banking system, but does not include a history of banking and credit during prior centuries, including details about the British Bank.
But Dr. Mehrling is correct in describing the modern examples. "This book tells the story of how the triumph of Moulton's shiftability view, as a consequence of depression and war as much as anything else, eventually led to the almost complete eclipse of the money view in modern discourse." He adds discussion of the theories developed by Knut Wicksell about interest rates. He sees the problem as: 'Instead of monitoring the balance between discipline and elasticity, the modern Fed attempts to keep the bank rate of interest in line with an ideal 'natural rate' of interest', the concept developed by Wicksell. He continues his critique: "Dominance of the economics and finance views meant that policymakers chose from a palette of policy options that was biased toward ease." He recommends his idea of 'money view' instead.

He then identifies his purpose: "This book seeks to begin that reconstruction by taking a resolutely money view approach to understanding the recent credit crisis, and by drawing lessons from that crisis for the future." That was written in 2011, now we can see that his recommendations were not accepted. The financial distortion as described by Nomi Prins and many others is worse today.

 
 

Chapter One - Lombard Street: Old and New
Dr. Mehrling gets right to the center of the financial problem. He quotes Hyman Minsky. "Capitalism is essentially a financial system, and the peculiar behavioral attributes of a capitalist economy center around the impact of finance on system behavior". (In other words, exchange of assets in the material world has been superceded by exchange in the financial (imaginary) world - ergo 'Financial capitalism'. He believes, correctly, that what is missing is a 'bridge' connecting the two. And he wants the central banks including the FED to build and control that bridge.

 
 

Chapter Two - Origins of the Present System
He opens by noting that when the creation of the FED created a different money system in 1913 the economic theories espoused by academics and financial operators did not change. "but it could not at the same time establish any new tradition of monetary thought." There had been no central bank since the Second Bank of the United States had been forced to expire by President Andrew Jackson in 1936.

'From National Banking to the Fed"
Dr. Mehrling discusses the Fed in relation to the prior National Banking System created during the Civil War to enable the Union government to finance its wartime expenditures. This was not a central bank. This was designed to force private banks to buy Federal government bonds with 2% interest and count these as its assets when generating liabilities as it issued 'note currency'. This was inflexible (inelastic) because it fixed the note supply, which was considered analogous to actual treasury issued currency. The required reserve ratios were also rigid. He describes how this system supported the market. He comments: "This is how the National Banking System was supposed to work but not in fact how it did work".
One problem was that the annual, seasonal shifts in the agricultural economy from planting to harvesting created the seasonal shift in the demand for credit denominated as money. The seasonal changes created seasonal changes in interest rates and financial crises in 1873, 1884, 1893 and 1907. He does not mention that there were similar financial crises prior to the Civil War and even prior to the American Revolution. He does not mention that a major political battle throughout the century was between creditors and debtors - the former demanding 'hard money' (that is fixed supply) and the debtors demanded 'soft money ( that is elastic money supply) which played out among other ways in the conflict between supporters of currency limited mostly to gold and supporters of expanding creation of currency out of silver.
Another topic he discusses in the prevalent theory of commercial loans. The law creating the Fed the requirement to address 'elasticity' in the money supply by dealing in commercial loans issued by the private banks. The commercial bank loans were to replace the Treasury government bonds as the collateral backing note issue (notes - that is credits, being the money used in market transactions. He comments that: "From this point of view, the most important innovation of the Federal Reserve System was to provide a routine mechanism for creation of reserve money in times of crisis." He believes that absent the catastrophe of World War I the bank might have developed organically

"From War Finance to Catastrophe"
The Federal reserve Act had with good reason prohibited the FED to buy Treasury credit as collateral securities. The conservative authors had recognized that would open the way for unlimited Treasury spending. But the Act was amended in September 1916 in order for the FED to help the Treasury to finance government expenditure on World War I.
He notes the origin of the subsequent problem. "hardly was the ink dry on the Act before the founding principle that notes could safely be issued only against self-liquidating commercial loans was simply shunted aside." and "Not only that, but Reserve Bank loans against government security collateral were subsequently pegged at a preferential rate, below the commercial rate below even the yield on the security itself."

When notes were exchanged for self-liquidating loans the credit-debt involved disappeared thus the money supply was not increased.

Mehrling sees the disaster: "Conservative bankers thus saw their worst nightmare realized, that the government would use its authority over the monetary apparatus to gain an advantage over private borrowers." But the same bankers quickly took advantage. "Federal debt expanded from about $1 billion in 1917 to $25 billion in 1919, with the Federal Reserve System itself absorbing about $2 billion and acting as fiscal agent to distribute much of the rest." He also notes that: "During the war, the Fed acted both to maintain liquidity in the Treasury bond market and to put a floor under the price of the bonds so that the Treasury could continue to borrow cheaply."
A similar policy was used during World War II.
Mehrling identifies the results: "This involvement of the fed in what would formerly have been considered speculative credit is probably one reason that, at the New York Fed anyway, attention shifted away from 'qualitative' control of credit, (limiting credit to productive use) and toward "quantitative' control, specifically discount rate policy directed at affecting the price of credit."

Here he has identified today's even more massive cause. Credit is not issued for productive use, but to finance consumption by favored groups who do not produce and have no other source of credit. But credit's other side is debt, the promise to produce in future something to complete the market exchange. The Fed absorbs that debt for the Treasury. Since the government cannot produce, it must confiscate production from private producers and also simply add to the debt ledger. Mehrling

 
 

Chapter Three - The Age of Management
Dr. Mehrling places great store in 'shiftability". I believe the transfer of an asset from one owner to another, as well as the use of an asset as collateral supporting a loan/debt is not so new. But he is focusing on the role of the FED in this regard. He cites the 1935 Bank act which 'meant that, from then on, the Fed was prepared to act fully as lender of last resort, accepting as collateral any' sound' asset and not limiting itself to short-term self-liquidating paper." It soon went further. In 1937 it took on the role to maintaining 'orderly conditions in the money market' quite generally." He considers this a very significant step. By providing 'shiftability' it took on the role of a security dealer.
Interesting is that his comments on the problems that created seem to be ignored in his conclusions.
He turns to describe the theory on his the interest created by a long term bond is the sum of the interest rates created by the short-term interest rates of the intervening years - except that in practice it is not. This has to do with the 'term structure' of interest rates (credit and debt). From this he narrates the financial market theories during the 1930's including EH - the expectations hypothesis. For example he writes: "Appealing as this theory is, it cannot be the whole story because in actual fact the term structure typically slopes upward."
This observation also applies to much of the difference between academic financial theories and the actual facts in the market place.
He devotes a section to the "Monetary Policy and the Employment Act" of 1946.
Another example. "In practice, even this simple idealized norm proved to be unrealizable in the rigid financial conditions inherited from the New Deal reforms." Then he turns to: "Listening to the Academics". Be careful what you ask for. Academic advice has not always been welcomed by the Fed, and for good reason." He points to the failure of Irving Fischer and then many others from divergent economics departments. Among the more famous are Leon Walras, Jacob Marschak, Harry Markowitz, James Tobin, and John Hicks, and of course Lord Keynes. These individuals competed for attention and acceptance by the government politicians.
For instance: "The Marschak-Tobin framework thus became the template for monetary practice as well as theory, once it got operationalized as the financial sector of the Fed's large-scale econometric model of the United States." He finds reason for plenty of concern about that model.
A choice comment: "Nevertheless, that was the ideal and so it became the Fed's job to achieve it.".

Ha - now we see another villain - the creation of econometrics as the standard basis for economics teaching in the famous universities.
Next, he enunciates "A Dissenting View"
Enter Hyman Minsky. But only long after Minsky's predictions came to fruition were they recognized. Rather, academic volleys were fired back and forth between Keynesians and Friedmanites.

Re his conclusions: But now the FED is stuffed full of these academic narrowly trained individuals who set policy according to preconceived concepts depicted in complex mathematical equations as the basis for econometrics. If not the MMT model, then which one rules today.

 
 

Chapter Four - The Art of the Swap
Dr. Mehrling continues with discussion of what took place despite Minsky's warning. "The pattern that Minsky was already noticing in domestic money markets in 1957, namely, financial innovation as a response to active money management, was also showing up in international money markets."
"After World war II, U.S. government debt was the coin of the realm internationally as well as domestically".. "Postwar Europe would be importing goods of all kinds from the United States and paying for them with dollars, so de facto the world trading system would be on a dollar standard."
Rather than gold, it was dollars that everyone received - some borrowed, some granted by the Marshall Plan and some by under valuing their foreign currency relative to the dollar.
There are several interesting points in this. Observant critics note that the real purpose of the Marshall Plan was not mainly to help Europe but to enable Europeans to buy U.S. production, thus helping avert unemployment. Undervaluing foreign currency, of course, over valued U.S. Dollars to the American domestic profit. And foreign borrowing U.S. dollars also helped the U.S. economy.
"From the start, the Bretton Woods system was built on a contradiction. It established a fixed exchange rate system internationally even as it endorsed uncoordinated macroeconomic management at the level of the nation state."... "The birth of the swap came as a way for individual firms to get around these national controls."

Currency Swap and the UIP Norm
"The essence of banking is a swap of IOU's"
This fact is not understood or appreciated by the general public, such as bank depositors or borrowers.

He discusses the 'swap' of currencies and the first example. He provides clear tabular depictions to show how these functioned. But the purpose, which he indicates, is what is particularly interesting. That purpose was to avoid ( get around) the legal regulations that governments placed in international currency flows. The politicians did not like it when their favored interest rates could result in investors generating a shift of their capital in response to higher interest rates elsewhere. And the expanding U.S. debt was pushed out by the Bretton Woods agrement. (U.S debt was created by U.S. purchasing materials by exchanging a credit instrument, that is a promise to exchange something of value later).
So not only investors, but manufacturers, and business men wanted to - needed to - move capital around in response to the results of normal import- export requirements. They achieved their goals by exchanging loans in different currencies. And they could protect from default risk by engaging a third party (in particular J.P Morgan bank) to generate a 'hedge'. At first J.P Morgan was a broker, but it soon became a dealer, the swaps were then intermediated, investable assets that unrelated entities could buy. Soon a currency market (actually credit/debt instruments) could be traded by entities using them as investments rather than to facilitate trade.
"One implication of the UIP norm is that the only way the United States can sustain significantly lower interest rates than the rest of the world is if the dollar is expected to appreciate against foreign currencies." ... "This was exactly the problem the United States faced in 1961". It needed to protect the relationship of he dollar to its value in gold. He describes the famous 'Operation Twist' as "an attempt to have it both ways".
But the concept and employment of the 'swap' mechanism was easily adapted for use in other exchanges.

Brave New World
Enter Fischer Black and his idea that a long term corporate bond could be divided into three 'tranches', each having a different risk and paying a different rate of interest. And these would then be held by different persons. The concept is to transfer risk. This involves different swaps of IOUs. Dr. Mehrling again provides balances sheet tables to illustrate the concept. He identifies the result. "The important point is that, because the swaps were arranged not as a swap of actual IOU's but rather as a swap of implicit IOU's they were not treated as loans for regulatory purposes."

Another effort to get around government financial controls. Now for the 'kicker'.

"It follows that Investor's risk hedge is only as good as his counterparty." ... "Now, as the previous discussion of currency swaps has made clear, the source of market liquidity in the swap market is the swap dealer who makes a two-way market by quoting both bid and ask prices. In the absence of such a dealer, if a counterparty defaults before the end of the contract, whatever risk was being transferred by the contract, reverts to its original holder, who must look around for another counterparty," .. "For the interest rate swap case, the Eurodollar forward market and the closely associated Eurodollar futures market provide a natural hedge." .. "For the credit default swap case, by contrast, there is no natural hedge available for dealers, and as a result the market has remained closer to a broker market than a proper dealer market." ... "The same logic, absence of someone wanting to speculate by selling risk when there are others who want to buy risk".
(Remember, selling risk means taking ON risk and buying risk means passing risk to some one else.)

"The same logic that explains the failure of UIP and EH also explains the failure of the natural norms on the CDS market, namely, the tendency of the market price of a CDS to reflect expected future default probability."

This is the cause he identifies, for the liquidity collapse in 2008. And his conclusion is that the FED must become that 'dealer of last resort' that will take on the risk.
From Modern Finance to Modern Macroeconomics
Dr. Mehrling notes that as the logic of arbitrage pricing norms occurred in the material sector - the real market, they also began to be recognized in the imaginary sector - the realm of theoretical understanding. This resulted in modern financial theory, and it then entered modern macroeconomics. He describes the history of this move in the writing of Tobin, Marschak, Markowitz, and Sharpe. "The result was the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) which ushered in modern finance." ... "This CAPM idea was applied first to equity markets, but similar reasoning soon revolutionized thinking about fixed income and currency markets as well, with important consequences for older thinking such as the expectations hypothesis of the term structure and the uncovered interest parity theory of exchange rates." ... "In practice EH and UIP continued not to fit the data very well."

Think of Yogi Beria when you read the next bit. "But now empirical failure could be attributed to problems with reality, no problems with theory -- to continuing inefficiency in market operations, not to counterfactual theoretical abstraction from liquidity risk." He continues by describing how arbitrage trades depended on market liquidity. He discussed further casualty of the "finance tsunami" in macroeconomics.

Tsunami - ha ha - if 2008-9 was a 'finance tsunami', what was 2020 -2021 and now 2022?
Yes, he mentions 'warning voices' such as Charles Goodhart and Robert Lucas who warned about the 'limits of economic management for other reasons.

Consider what 'disinermediation' means for the banking and 'shadow banking' systems.
"As in financial theory, so too in macroeconomics theory, the guiding norm was an ideal world with perfect liquidity,. as in financial practice driven by the profit motive, so too in economic policy practice driven by a welfare motive, deviations between the ideal world and the real world were conceived as opportunities for arbitrage."
The result, he states, is that the financial regulators became complicit partners with investors in the market in their attempt to make liquidity in the real world a free good as it was considered to be in the imaginary, ideal economic theory.

 

Chapter Five - What Do Dealers Do?

Well, they deal. They live and function in either or both the material market world and the imaginary financial world. There is a theoretical concept about liquidity in the imaginary sector and a practical result of liquidity in the material sector. In the first it is ignored and in the second it is critical. Dr. Mehrling's central concern is the practical loss of recognition of the "money view perspective."

Inside the Money Market
"The logical origin of the money market can be traced, perhaps unsurprisingly, to the operations of a decentralized payment system."
Dr. Mehrling considers what the credit-debt system that funds the market would be if the US had but one bank in which everyone deposited and from which received loans. But we actually have a "single integrated banking system, and the key to that integration is the money market." One result is that banks depend for 'payments elasticity' on interbank credit swaps. Each bank must end each day with a positive balance. But they hold almost no reserves and instead will loan and borrow from each other over night in the federal funds market held at the Federal Reserve so that the net result is zero. For banks not members of the FED system they can borrow and loan in the Eurodollar market or directly between each other in the 'repro market'. Of course these loans generate various sized interest. It is during a crisis that these interest rates can and do greatly increase. To borrow the bank must present collateral acceptable to the loaning bank. In case of a mismatch a bank can go to the FED 'discount window', but banks hate to do that because it can be seen as 'questionable' bank, and the 'discount window' demands a significant fee. The FED will try to act before stress takes place by intervening daily. The purpose and goal of all this is to make the entire banking system function as if it were a single bank.

Funding Liquidity and Market Liquidity
Actually, the 'repro system' was created before there was a federal funds system. During the 19th century the independent banks would transfer money between each other to accomplish the same purpose. This system created 'dealers' in the repro market. Again, a dealer establishes his own capital or line of credit and that enables him to stand as an intermediatory by offering a two-way market in buying and selling securities in this repro-market.
"Here we find the historical origin of the connection between funding liquidity and market liquidity that is so central to modern arrangements."
This is the author's central subject - establishment of a dealer system supported by creating a bridge between the two is the task he wants the FED and central banks in general, to assume officially and continuously, not only as an emergency measure. He illustrates this with more balance sheets. It depicts buying and selling in both the Treasury bond and 'bill' markets, funding its operations in the repro-market. The entire activity appears to be complex, and it is, but he attempts to make is seem simple.
Anatomy of a Crisis
He uses examples of shifts in the balance sheets of participants during a crisis created by a shift in the desires of wealth holders for money instead of securities. It is all about the cash flows - in and out - for private wealth holders versus the dealers and banks. Again, he is considering liquidity. "The Fed (in his example and his desire) in a crisis is not so much the lender of last resort (funding [financial] liquidity) as it is the dealer of last resort (market liquidity).
Again, I explain, this is a bridge between the imaginary financial world and the material market world.
His claim is: "Under modern conditions, backstop of market liquidity requires the Fed to serve as dealer of last resort"

Monetary Policy
Here he discusses what he identifies as a fundamental difference between earlier bank - monetary - operations based on a 'money theory' and the modern academic economic view which ignores it. "From the perspective of the classic money view, monetary policy was all about using 'bank rate' to influence the balance of elasticity and discipline that is imposed by the survival constraint that faces each individual entity in the system." .. "Current macroeconomic thinking is organized around something called the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model, which we can understand loosely as a jazzed-up version of the Walrasian equilibrium model that was at the center of the thinking of a previous generation." ... "Where this standard economics view confronts the money view most directly is on the question of how to set the federal funds rate, a question on which proponents of the economics view have developed a common stance that goes under the heading "Inflation Targeting". ... "More or less all modern academic debate is organized as argument about the appropriate quantitative settings for a Taylor rule."
"In the money view perspective, if the Fed fails to raise interest rates in the face of a credit -fueled asset price bubble, the bubble will feed on itself, growing ever larger and having ever greater distorting effects, until it bursts." ... "It follows that if funding costs are distorted by monetary policy, then a fortiori so will be asset prices that are already liquid, and most effect on the price of assets that are most liquid." ... "The money view emphasizes the inherent instability of a credit system driven by the private profit motive, but the problem is made worse when the Fed adopts a policy rule that denies any responsibility for preventing a bubble." "The problem is that the music does not just stop, it switches into reverse." ... "At its core, our monetary system is a dealer system that supports the liquidity of our securities markets, and the Fed serves as dealer-in-chief not only in wartime but also in peacetime, and especially in financial crisis time."

Sounds like today.

But the academic economics industry does not recognize a 'money view perspective'. Ignoring it, or refusing to admit it was the central goal of the progressives in creating the FED and then abandoning any restraint on the money supply by linking it to gold was essential for funding the 'welfare state'. ...

Now we have moved even further into imaginary theory with the advocacy of "Modern Money Theory - MMT".

 
 

Chapter Six - Learning from the Crisis

Dr. Mehrling comments that from the money perspective the financial crisis of 2007-8 was a stress test of the new world modern finance system. It featured the creation of currency swaps, then interest rate swaps and then credit default swaps which resulted in a 'transformation' of a rigid and highly regulated financial system. "The result is that now we have a capital-market-based credit system that is now a more important source of credit than the traditional banking system."
(That is the 'shadow bank' system). In this chapter Dr. Mehrling narrates and analyses the change that has taken place between the role of the central bank in Bagehot's time. He states that the reality of the capital markets (credit-debt) is different now, but the economic theory that explains it has not kept up. So we need a new understanding of monetary policy and financial regulation. Our memory remains thinking of the traditional local bank that took in deposits and used that capital to make local loans. The liquidity risk amounted to depositors withdrawing their money while the bank had invested it or lent it for longer terms. Since the great depression these deposits have been insured by the government. He shows with sample balance sheets what happens when 'shadow banks' enter the money arena. They fund their operations by issuing money market securities purchased by money market mutual funds. Their assets are ABCP - asset-backed commercial paper and repro (RP) instruments. Their solvency and liquidity risks are not protected. During the financial crisis in 2007-8 it was these accounts that collapsed. They were rescued temporarily. But when Bear and Lehman collapsed and then AIG as well. Not only did the FED become a dealer of last resort but the Congress had to enable the Treasury to step in as well. Still, the thinking about the needed response was outdated.
He summarizes the thinking: "When liquidity risk was thought to be the issue, it was the Fed's problem; when solvency risk was thought to be the issue, it became the Treasury's problem "It became not a need to save a bank but to save the entire banking system (including international banking). The entire market-based credit system was at risk. It was the inability to fund liquidity. He states that the economists largely missed the most important point."

Here is a key explanation.
What had happened was that the liquidity of the securities in the money market was based on 'implicit' collateral - the net worth on the balance sheets that was used for unsecured money market funding. When that collateral had an unreliable value it was worthless as a security.
"But why did collateral valuations come under threat? Fundamental valuation was definitely as concern - bad loans had definitely been made - but from a money view perspective price is first of all a matter of market liquidity, and this perspective focuses attention on the dealer system that translated funding liquidity into market liquidity."
What does he mean by this? It rests on the real meaning of 'money' and the concept of' 'value'. He takes pages to explain, bringing in the investment banks and the=CDO (collateralized debt obligations) Dealers in this balance their own sheet by matching sales of risk to those asking for it and buying risk from those willing to sell it. But nothing has 'intrinsic' value. Something has the relative value (quantified by the metric "money') set by the entity willing to take it in exchange for something it will give up. But in the crisis no one could determine what the relative monetary value of the collateral at offer was. And much of the collateral at offer was one 'tranch' part of a complex underling debt (for instance a mortgage.). Worse, prior to the crisis both investment banks and insurance companies were selling very cheap credit insurance. From Dr. Mehrling's discussion it is apparent that many actors did not know what they were really doing, not what they thought they were doing.

Dealer of Last Resort
In this section Dr. Mehrling describes what the FED and the Treasury did to rescue the financial system. For the FED it included creation of an allthabet soup of special purpose offices that could lend (created credit to specific entities and create a balance sheet for imaginary assets and liabilities) The TSLF - Term securities Lending Facility - a Money Market Investment Funding Facility - A Term asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF) . The Treasury put Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into conservatorship by exchanging Treasury debt for the debt of Fannie and Fredie. The FED took over AIG's book of credit derivatives - the CDS portfolio. He does not include it, but the FED also engaged in currency swaps with foreign banks to enable them to bail out their investors who held US investments.

He sees that: "The Fed has been acting as dealer of last resort, not just in the credit insurance market, which was the source of market liquidity precrisis, but now in the capital market directly.".. The Fed now recognizes that, for our market-based credit system, it must remake itself as dealer of last resort.".

Danielle DiMartino Booth gives a much longer list of these FED special organiztions created to rescue specific parts of the 'shadow banking system.

 
 

Conclusion:
The author considers that the 'intellectual blinders' (that is antiquated economic theory) that he describes in Chapter Three include excessive appreciation of Moulton's shiftability and Martin's dealer system and insufficient appreciation of their limitations.
But the Rubicon has already been forded. He presumes: "What are the implications of the Fed's new role as 'dealer of last resort' for normal times? Yes , no longer a response to a 'once in a lifetime emergency', but a constant standard function of the central bank. His basis is: "the realization that our market-based credit system relies critically on two-way dealer markets that link funding liquidity in the money market with market liquidity in the capital market."

Here is the core of the take over. "The Fed must think of its role as intervening to support and manage that system as a whole, not just to set the price in a narrow slice of the funding markets." YES 'support and manage'. Yes, this is management by academic 'know-it-alls' who could not manage the Fed's check book and have no personal experience in business, large or small. He elaborates on the theory of his proposal. But throughout the book he stresses the difference between the activity in the theoretical concepts and the actions in real money markets. In his chapter on Management he cites mismanagement. "Yet in his conclusions he gives scant attention to the bias, skill, preconceptions, not to mention political agendas of the personnel IN the FED; the political self-preservation of the FED institution; and the political desires of the FED's overlords.

 
{short description of image}

Walter Bagehot, Lombard Street

 
{short description of image}

Wikipedia entry, Lombard Street

 
{short description of image}

Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff, This Time is Different

 
{short description of image}

David Chambers and Elroy Dimson, Financial Market History: Reflections on the Past for Investors Today

 
{short description of image}

Barry Eichengreen, Exorbitant Privilege: The Rise and Fall of the Dollar and the Future of the International Monetary System

 
{short description of image}

 
{short description of image}

Justin Fox, The Myth of the Rational Market,

 
{short description of image}

George Cooper, The Origin of Financial Crises

 
{short description of image}

Nomi Prins, Collu$ion, How Central Bankers Rigged the World

 
{short description of image}

Danielle DiMartino Booth, FED UP: An Insider's take on Why the Federal Reserve is Bad for America

 
{short description of image}

L. Randal Wray, Modern Money Theory: MMT

 
{short description of image}

William Bonner and Lili Rajiva, Mobs, Messiahs, and Markets

 
{short description of image}

 

Return to Xenophon.